Manifesto

flattr this!

Preamble

Click here for this post in PDF

The fundamental cause of the economic and financial crisis that began in late 2007 was lending by the finance sector that primarily financed speculation rather than investment. The private debt bubble this caused is unprecedented, probably in human history and certainly in the last century (see Figure 1). Its unwinding now is the primary cause of the sustained slump in economic growth. The recent growth in sovereign debt is a symptom of this underlying crisis, not the cause, and the current political obsession with reducing sovereign debt will exacerbate the root problem of private sector deleveraging.

Figure 1

US private debt clearly rose faster than GDP from the end of World War II (when the debt to GDP ratio was 43%) until 2009 (when it peaked at 303%), but there is no intrinsic reason why it (or the public sector debt to GDP ratio) has to rise over time. I give a theoretical explanation elsewhere (Keen 2010), but an empirical comparison will suffice here: 1945 till 1965 were the best years of the Australian economy—with unemployment averaging 2 percent—and during that time the private debt ratio remained relatively constant at 25% of GDP (see Figure 2).

Figure 2

America's minimum private debt ratio in 1945 may have been artificially low in the aftermath of both the Great Depression and World War II (and there are good reasons why the US economy should have a higher sustainable debt ratio than does Australia), but at some time between 1945 and America's first post-WWII financial crisis in 1966 (Minsky 1982, p. xiii), it passed this level.

The explosion in speculative debt drove asset prices to all-time highs—relative to consumer prices—from which they are now inexorably collapsing (see Figure 3 and Figure 4).

Figure 3

Figure 4

The debt and asset price bubbles were ignored by conventional "Neoclassical" economists on the basis of a set of a priori beliefs about the nature of a market economy that are spurious, but deeply entrenched. Understanding how this crisis came about will require a new, dynamic, monetary approach to economic theory that contradicts the neat, plausible and false Neoclassical model that currently dominates academic economics and popular political debate.

Escaping from the debt trap we are now in will require either a "Lost Generation", or policies that run counter to conventional economic thought and the short-term interests of the financial sector.

Preventing a future crisis will require a redefinition of financial claims upon the real economy which eliminates the appeal of leveraged speculation.

These three observations lead to the three primary objectives of Debtwatch:

  1. To develop a realistic, empirically based, dynamic monetary approach to economic theory and policy;
  2. To develop and promote a "modern Jubilee" by which private debt can be reduced while doing the minimum possible harm to aggregate demand and social equity; and
  3. To develop and promote new definitions of shares and property ownership that will minimize the destructive instabilities of capitalism and promote its creative instabilities.

A realistic economics

The economic and financial crisis has been caused by unenlightened self-interest and fraudulent behaviour on an unprecedented scale. But this behaviour could not have grown so large were it not for the cover given to this behaviour by the dominant theory of economics, which is known as "Neoclassical Economics".

Though many commentators call this theory "Keynesian", one of Keynes's objectives in the 1930s was to overthrow this theory, but instead, as the memory of the Great Depression receded, academic economists gradually constructed an even more extreme version of Neoclassical economics than that against which Keynes had fought. This began with Hicks's "IS-LM" model, which is still accepted as representing "Keynesian" economics today, but which was in fact a Neoclassical model derived two years before the General Theory was published:

The IS-LM diagram, which is widely, but not universally, accepted as a convenient synopsis of Keynesian theory, is a thing for which I cannot deny that I have some responsibility... "Mr. Keynes and the Classics" (Hicks 1937) was actually the fourth of the relevant papers which I wrote during those years… But there were two others that I had written before I saw The General Theory… "Wages and Interest: the Dynamic Problem" (Hicks 1935) was a first sketch of what was to become the "dynamic" model of Value and Capital (Hicks 1939). It is important here, because it shows (I think quite conclusively) that that [IS-LM] model was already in my mind before I wrote even the first of my papers on Keynes. (Hicks 1981, pp. 139-140; emphasis added; see also Keen 2011)

As it grew more virulent, neoclassical theory encouraged politicians to remove the barriers to fraud that were erected in the wake of the last great economic crisis, the Great Depression, in the naïve belief that a deregulated economy necessarily reaches a harmonious equilibrium:

'Macroeconomics was born as a distinct field in the 1940's, as a part of the intellectual response to the Great Depression. The term then referred to the body of knowledge and expertise that we hoped would prevent the recurrence of that economic disaster. My thesis in this lecture is that macroeconomics in this original sense has succeeded: Its central problem of depression prevention has been solved, for all practical purposes, and has in fact been solved for many decades.' (Lucas 2003 , p. 1 ; emphasis added)

Regulators in its thrall—such as Greenspan and Bernanke—rescued the financial sector from a series of crises, with each one leading to yet another until ultimately this one, from which no return to "business as usual" is possible.

Neoclassical economics therefore played an important role in making this crisis as extreme as it became. It is time to succeed where Keynes failed, by both eliminating this theory and replacing it with a realistic alternative.

Critiquing Neoclassical economics

Keynes was scathing about what he called "Classical Economics", and what we today call Neoclassical Economics, lambasting its treatment of time, expectations, uncertainty and money, and the stability or otherwise of capitalism:

I accuse the classical economic theory of being itself one of these pretty, polite techniques which tries to deal with the present by abstracting from the fact that we know very little about the future…. a classical economist … has overlooked the precise nature of the difference which his abstraction makes between theory and practice … particularly the case in his treatment of Money…

This that I offer is, therefore, a theory of why output and employment are so liable to fluctuation.

The orthodox theory assumes that we have a knowledge of the future of a kind quite different from that which we actually possess… The hypothesis of a calculable future leads to a wrong interpretation of the principles of behavior which the need for action compels us to adopt, and to an underestimation of the concealed factors of utter doubt, precariousness, hope and fear (Keynes 1937, pp. 215-222)

Keynes's failure to overthrow Neoclassical economics led instead to its reconstruction after the Great Depression in an even more extreme form. This process culminated in "Rational Expectations" macroeconomics in which, rather than dealing with the present "by abstracting from the fact that we know very little about the future", deals with it by assuming we can accurately predict the future!:

I should like to suggest that expectations, since they are informed predictions of future events, are essentially the same as the predictions of the relevant economic theory. (Muth 1961, p. 316)

In the preceding section, the hypothesis of adaptive expectations was rejected as a component of the natural rate hypothesis on the grounds that, under some policy [the gap between actual and expected inflation] is non-zero. If the impossibility of a non-zero value … is taken as an essential feature of the natural rate theory, one is led simply to adding the assumption that [the gap between actual and expected inflation] is zero as an additional axiom… or to assume that expectations are rational in the sense of Muth. (Lucas 1972, p. 54; emphasis added)

I wrote Debunking Economics (Keen 2001; Keen 2011) to help prevent a Neoclassical revival recurring after our current crisis is over. Here I have the advantage of time over Keynes: when he wrote The General Theory, the flaws in neoclassical economics were only vaguely specified—and Keynes himself kept many of those concepts alive, such as the marginal productivity theory of income distribution:

For every value of [total employment] there is a corresponding marginal productivity of labour in the wage-goods industries; and it is this which determines the real wage. (Keynes 1936, p. 27)

Since then, the flaws have been fully detailed, by critics like Sraffa (Sraffa 1960) at one extreme to "own goals" like the Sonnenschein-Mantel-Debreu conditions at the other (Sonnenschein 1973; Shafer and Sonnenschein 1993). The ambition of Debunking Economics was to make the many flaws in neoclassical economics so well known that, should the economy ever experience another Great Depression, it would be that much harder for Neoclassical economics to survive (for more, see Debunking Economics: the naked emperor dethroned?;or buy the book: Amazon USA; Amazon UK; Kindle USA; Kindle UK; Abbey's Australia).

I also provide critiques of conventional economic theory in my lectures, which I make more broadly available via Youtube videos.

Developing an alternative

The seeds of an alternative, realistic theory were developed by Hyman Minsky in the Financial Instability Hypothesis (FIH), which itself reflected the wisdom of the great non-neoclassical economists Marx, Veblen, Schumpeter, Fisher and Keynes, and the historical record of capitalism that had included periodic Depressions (as well as the dramatic technological transformation of production). As Minsky argued, an economic theory could not claim to represent capitalism unless it could explain those periodic crises:

Can "It"—a Great Depression—happen again? And if "It" can happen, why didn't "It" occur in the years since World War II? These are questions that naturally follow from both the historical record and the comparative success of the past thirty-five years. To answer these questions it is necessary to have an economic theory which makes great depressions one of the possible states in which our type of capitalist economy can find itself. (Minsky 1982, p. 5)

Minsky developed a coherent verbal model of his hypothesis, but his own attempt to develop a mathematical model in his PhD (Minsky 1957) was unsuccessful (Keen 2000), and he subsequently abandoned that endeavour.

Using insights from complexity theory, I developed models on the FIH that capture its fundamental proposition, that a market economy can experience a debt-deflation (Fisher 1933) after a series of debt-financed cycles (Keen 1995; Keen 1996; Keen 1997; Keen 2000). These models generated a period of declining volatility in employment and wages with a rising ration of debt to GDP, followed by a period of rising volatility before an eventual debt-induced breakdown. They led me to caution that:

From the perspective of economic theory and policy, this vision of a capitalist economy with finance requires us to go beyond that habit of mind which Keynes described so well, the excessive reliance on the (stable) recent past as a guide to the future. The chaotic dynamics explored in this paper should warn us against accepting a period of relative tranquility in a capitalist economy as anything other than a lull before the storm. (Keen, 1995, p. 634; emphasis added)

The empirical data and the implications of these models led me to expect and warn of an impending serious economic crisis (Keen 2006; Keen 2007) at a time when Neoclassical economists were waxing lyrical about "The Great Moderation"(Bernanke 2004; Bernanke 2004; Summers 2005; Campbell 2007; Benati 2008; D'Agostino and Whelan 2008; Gian­none, Lenza et al. 2008; Canova 2009; Gali and Gam­betti 2009; Wood­ford 2009; Bean 2010).

The cri­sis itself emphat­i­cally makes the point that a new the­ory of eco­nom­ics is needed, in which cap­i­tal­ism is seen as a dynamic, mon­e­tary sys­tem with both cre­ative and destruc­tive insta­bil­i­ties, where those destruc­tive insta­bil­i­ties emanate over­whelm­ingly from the finan­cial sector.

Spe­cific projects

The Cen­ter for Eco­nomic Sta­bil­ity Incorporated

With the sup­port of blog mem­bers, I have formed the Cen­ter for Eco­nomic Sta­bil­ity Incor­po­rated. Our objec­tive is to develop CfESI into an empirically-oriented think-tank on eco­nom­ics that will develop real­is­tic analy­sis of cap­i­tal­ism, and pro­mote poli­cies based upon that analy­sis. The suc­cess of CfESI is depen­dent upon rais­ing suf­fi­cient fund­ing to enable staff to be hired who can take over the admin­is­tra­tive and web duties from me, and sup­ple­ment my research efforts.

Min­sky”

Named in honor of Hyman Min­sky, this is a com­puter pro­gram that enables a com­plex mon­e­tary sys­tem to be mod­elled with rel­a­tive ease. The pro­gram imple­ments the tab­u­lar approach to mod­el­ling finan­cial flows devel­oped in (Keen 2008; Keen 2010; Keen 2011), and com­bines this with the “flow­chart” par­a­digm devel­oped by engi­neers to model phys­i­cal processes, and imple­mented in numer­ous soft­ware pro­grams (Simulink, Vis­sim, Ven­sim, Ithink, Stella, etc.). It will be both a ped­a­gogic tool to make dynamic mon­e­tary mod­el­ling easy and attrac­tive to new stu­dents, and a pow­er­ful research tool that will enable the con­struc­tion of real­is­tic, mon­e­tary mod­els of capitalism.

Fig­ure 5

  • A first ver­sion of Min­sky is already under devel­op­ment, with fund­ing pro­vided by a grant from the Insti­tute for New Eco­nomic Think­ing. This ver­sion, to be com­pleted in mid-2012, will enable the mod­el­ling of the econ­omy as a mon­e­tary dynamic sin­gle com­mod­ity sys­tem. A pro­to­type will be released in early 2012. A Source­forge page is now oper­at­ing, and we will shortly be open­ing it up for col­lab­o­ra­tion by Open Source developers.
  • Ver­sion 2.0 will enable multi-commodity input-output dynam­ics to be mod­elled, as well as a dis­ag­gre­gated bank­ing sec­tor. A seed­ing grant to help develop ver­sion 2.0 has been recently been received from the Insti­tute for New Eco­nomic Think­ing. This will be com­bined with grants from other pri­vate enti­ties to make an appli­ca­tion for sup­port under the Aus­tralian Research Council’s Link­age pro­gram for up to A$500,000 p.a. of fur­ther fund­ing. One Aus­tralian firm has already com­mit­ted to be an Indus­try Part­ner in this appli­ca­tion, and I wel­come addi­tional sup­port from other firms, whether Aus­tralian or oth­er­wise (a min­i­mum con­tri­bu­tion of A$50,000 over 3 years is required to qual­ify as an Indus­try Part­ner under ARC rules).
  • Ver­sion 3.0 will add the capa­bil­ity to model inter­na­tional trade and finan­cial flows.

The pro­gram will be plat­form inde­pen­dent, and freely avail­able under the GPL licence.

Inte­grat­ing Min­sky with bio­phys­i­cal data

Min­sky as it stands is purely a sim­u­la­tion tool. How­ever, as part of a United Nations Envi­ron­ment Pro­gram projectResource Effi­ciency: Eco­nom­ics and Out­look for Asia-Pacific”, a pre­cur­sor to Min­sky has been linked to a bio­phys­i­cal data­base known as ASFF (for “Aus­tralian Stocks and Flows Foun­da­tion”) devel­oped by the CSIRO (Turner, Hoff­man et al. 2011),. Our long term ambi­tion is to com­bine the two sys­tems seam­lessly, so that the phys­i­cal para­me­ters of Min­sky will be derived directly from empir­i­cal data (which can be derived for any national econ­omy) and so that Minsky’s fit to empir­i­cal data can be tested.

 

 

Fig­ure 6
The sec­ond stage of this process is part of the pro­posal for which I have just received fur­ther fund­ing from INET.

Finance and Eco­nomic Breakdown

This will be a book-length treat­ment of the Finan­cial Insta­bil­ity Hypoth­e­sis that I hope will form one of the foun­da­tions of a post-Neoclassical macro­eco­nom­ics. Writ­ing a book like this takes time and iso­la­tion, two things I have had very lit­tle of in the past six years since I first started warn­ing of an impend­ing eco­nomic cri­sis (Keen 2005). I have delayed the writ­ing of this “mag­num opus” for over a decade; in 2012–13 I intend devot­ing as much time as I can to writ­ing it, which neces­si­tates min­imis­ing time spent on other activ­i­ties such as the main­te­nance of this blog.

Keen­Data

Cur­rently I pull in data from over 1500 dif­fer­ent sources into a Math­cad work­sheet on my PC. Math­cad, with a lit­tle help from my pro­gram­ming, does a won­der­ful job of analysing and dis­play­ing the data. But the nam­ing con­ven­tions in my pseudo-database are … a joke, there are none. Con­se­quently, only some­one inti­mately acquainted with the data can use my sys­tem, and at the moment that’s just me. I also have to man­u­ally down­load files when they are updated. Thanks to Mathcad’s vis­i­ble equa­tions, audit­ing the data is cer­tainly eas­ier than with a spread­sheet, but it is still dif­fi­cult com­pared to a well-structured rela­tional database.

A sup­porter has devel­oped an online sys­tem, cur­rently called Econ­o­data, to over­come these limitations:

  • The data is stored in a “Ruby on Rails” rela­tional database;
  • The sys­tem auto­mat­i­cally updates data when it is altered by providers;
  • The rela­tional data­base sys­tem and a 4GL for derived data series makes audit­ing straight­for­ward, and the sys­tem gen­er­ates a tinyURL so that a com­plex data series or chart can be eas­ily repli­cated by any­one; and
  • It will be eas­ily acces­si­ble and usable by sub­scribers to Debt­watch and CfESI.

Econ­o­data is cur­rently unavail­able since it is being ported to a new server, and the data­base is rel­a­tively unpop­u­lated. The data­base will also sup­port my book Finance and Eco­nomic Break­down, by mak­ing it pos­si­ble for read­ers to ver­ify any empir­i­cal charts for them­selves sim­ply by typ­ing its TinyURL into a browser.

Credit-aware Eco­nomic Indicators

My debt-aware per­spec­tive on eco­nom­ics makes it easy to explain what Bernanke has admit­ted is still inex­plic­a­ble to him: where the cri­sis came from, and why it is persisting:

Part of the slow­down is tem­po­rary, and part of it may be longer-lasting. We do believe that growth is going to pick up going into 2012 but at a some­what slower pace than we had antic­i­pated in April. We don’t have a pre­cise read on why this slower pace of growth is per­sist­ing… ” His admis­sion of igno­rance reflects gen­uine puz­zle­ment with the economy’s fail­ure to reach what he likes to call escape veloc­ity. (G.I. 2011)

In a nut­shell, the change in total pri­vate debt is a key deter­mi­nant of aggre­gate demand, and the turn­around from increas­ing debt boost­ing demand from incomes alone by 28% in 2008 to reduc­ing demand below this level by 20 per­cent in early 2010 was the cause of the crisis.

Fig­ure 7

Sim­i­larly, the slow­down in the rate of decline of debt from its max­i­mum rate of decline of almost US$3 tril­lion p.a. to a mere $340 bil­lion p.a. is—along with the growth in gov­ern­ment debt—the main rea­son why the cri­sis has atten­u­ated slightly, rather than plung­ing into Great Depres­sion depths of unemployment.

Fig­ure 8

One indi­ca­tor that has arisen out of my work—building on orig­i­nal work by Biggs, Mayer and Pick (Biggs and Mayer 2010; Biggs, Mayer et al. 2010)—is the “Credit Accel­er­a­tor” (Keen 2011, pp. 160–165), which was first called the “Credit Impulse”. Both the change in income and the accel­er­a­tion of credit deter­mine the rate of change of eco­nomic activ­ity, and these are cor­re­lated with each other (the R2 since 1980 is 0.56), but the eco­nom­ics col­lapse in late 2007 was clearly dri­ven pri­mar­ily by the rapid and unprece­dented decel­er­a­tion of debt.

Fig­ure 9

Debt accel­er­a­tion is the main fac­tor in deter­min­ing asset prices. Asset bub­bles there­fore have to burst, because debt accel­er­a­tion can­not remain pos­i­tive forever.

Fig­ure 10

This causal rela­tion­ship is much more obvi­ous with mort­gage debt and change in house prices (see Fig­ure 11).

Fig­ure 11

Fur­ther devel­op­ment of this indi­ca­tor is there­fore highly warranted—both as an indi­ca­tor of what trends can be expected in asset prices now, and as a means to iden­tify whether a bub­ble is devel­op­ing in future. At present, the Credit Accelerator’s def­i­n­i­tion is quite simple—the change in change in debt over a time period, divided by GDP at the mid­point of that period—and the nois­i­ness of finan­cial data makes it dif­fi­cult to use short time peri­ods, which would obvi­ously be supe­rior for fore­cast­ing. A sophis­ti­cated fil­ter­ing process and for­ward indi­ca­tors for credit would make the Credit Accel­er­a­tor a much more pow­er­ful tool.

A Mod­ern Jubilee

Michael Hudson’s sim­ple phrase that “Debts that can’t be repaid, won’t be repaid” sums up the eco­nomic dilemma of our times. This does not involve sanc­tion­ing “moral haz­ard”, since the real moral haz­ard was in the behav­iour of the finance sec­tor in cre­at­ing this debt in the first place. Most of this debt should never have been cre­ated, since all it did was fund dis­guised Ponzi Schemes that inflated asset val­ues with­out adding to society’s pro­duc­tiv­ity. Here the irresponsibility—and Moral Hazard—clearly lay with the lenders rather than the borrowers.

The only real ques­tion we face is not whether we should or should not repay this debt, but how are we going to go about not repay­ing it?

The stan­dard means of reduc­ing debt—personal and cor­po­rate bank­rupt­cies for some, slow repay­ment of debt in depressed eco­nomic con­di­tions for others—could have us mired in delever­ag­ing for one and a half decades, given its cur­rent rate (see Fig­ure 12).

Fig­ure 12

That fate would in turn mean one and a half decades where the boost to demand that ris­ing debt should provide—when it finances invest­ment rather than speculation—will not be there. The econ­omy will tend to grow more slowly than is needed to absorb new entrants into the work­force, inno­va­tion will slow down, and jus­ti­fied polit­i­cal unrest will rise—with poten­tially unjus­ti­fied social consequences.

We don’t need to spec­u­late about the eco­nomic and social dam­age such a future his­tory will cause—all we have to do is remem­ber the last time.

We should, there­fore, find a means to reduce the pri­vate debt bur­den now, and reduce the length of time we spend in this dam­ag­ing process of delever­ag­ing. Pre-capitalist soci­eties insti­tuted the prac­tice of the Jubilee to escape from sim­i­lar traps (Hud­son 2000; Hud­son 2004), and debt defaults have been a reg­u­lar expe­ri­ence in the his­tory of cap­i­tal­ism too (Rein­hart and Rogoff 2008). So a prima facie alter­na­tive to 15 years of delever­ag­ing would be an old-fashioned debt Jubilee.

But a Jubilee in our mod­ern cap­i­tal­ist sys­tem faces two dilem­mas. Firstly, in any cap­i­tal­ist sys­tem, a debt Jubilee would paral­yse the finan­cial sec­tor by destroy­ing bank assets. Sec­ondly, in our era of secu­ri­tized finance, the own­er­ship of debt per­me­ates soci­ety in the form of asset based secu­ri­ties (ABS) that gen­er­ate income streams on which a mul­ti­tude of non-bank recip­i­ents depend, from indi­vid­u­als to coun­cils to pen­sion funds.

Debt abo­li­tion would inevitably also destroy both the assets and the income streams of own­ers of ABSs, most of whom are inno­cent bystanders to the delu­sion and fraud that gave us the Sub­prime Cri­sis, and the myr­iad fias­cos that Wall Street has per­pe­trated in the 2 decades since the 1987 Stock Mar­ket Crash.

We there­fore need a way to short-circuit the process of debt-deleveraging, while not destroy­ing the assets of both the bank­ing sec­tor and the mem­bers of the non-banking pub­lic who pur­chased ABSs. One fea­si­ble means to do this is a “Mod­ern Jubilee”, which could also be described as “Quan­ti­ta­tive Eas­ing for the public”.

Quan­ti­ta­tive Eas­ing was under­taken in the false belief that this would “kick start” the econ­omy by spurring bank lending.

And although there are a lot of Amer­i­cans who under­stand­ably think that gov­ern­ment money would be bet­ter spent going directly to fam­i­lies and busi­nesses instead of banks – “where’s our bailout?,” they ask – the truth is that a dol­lar of cap­i­tal in a bank can actu­ally result in eight or ten dol­lars of loans to fam­i­lies and busi­nesses, a mul­ti­plier effect that can ulti­mately lead to a faster pace of eco­nomic growth. (Obama 2009, p. 3; empha­sis added)

Instead, its main effect was to dra­mat­i­cally increase the idle reserves of the bank­ing sec­tor while the broad money sup­ply stag­nated or fell, (see Fig­ure 13), for the obvi­ous rea­sons that there is already too much pri­vate sec­tor debt, and nei­ther lenders nor the pub­lic want to take on more debt.

Fig­ure 13

A Mod­ern Jubilee would cre­ate fiat money in the same way as with Quan­ti­ta­tive Eas­ing, but would direct that money to the bank accounts of the pub­lic with the require­ment that the first use of this money would be to reduce debt. Debtors whose debt exceeded their injec­tion would have their debt reduced but not elim­i­nated, while at the other extreme, recip­i­ents with no debt would receive a cash injec­tion into their deposit accounts.

The broad effects of a Mod­ern Jubilee would be:

  1. Debtors would have their debt level reduced;
  2. Non-debtors would receive a cash injection;
  3. The value of bank assets would remain con­stant, but the dis­tri­b­u­tion would alter with debt-instruments declin­ing in value and cash assets rising;
  4. Bank income would fall, since debt is an income-earning asset for a bank while cash reserves are not;
  5. The income flows to asset-backed secu­ri­ties would fall, since a sub­stan­tial pro­por­tion of the debt back­ing such secu­ri­ties would be paid off; and
  6. Mem­bers of the pub­lic (both indi­vid­u­als and cor­po­ra­tions) who owned asset-backed-securities would have increased cash hold­ings out of which they could spend in lieu of the income stream from ABS’s on which they were pre­vi­ously dependent.

Clearly there are numer­ous com­plex issues to be con­sid­ered in such a pol­icy: the scale of money cre­ation needed to have a sig­nif­i­cant pos­i­tive impact (with­out exces­sive neg­a­tive effects—there will obvi­ously be such effects, but their impor­tance should be judged against the alter­na­tive of con­tin­ued delever­ag­ing); the mechan­ics of the money cre­ation process itself (which could repli­cate those of Quan­ti­ta­tive Eas­ing, but may also require changes to the legal pro­hi­bi­tion of Reserve Banks from buy­ing gov­ern­ment bonds directly from the Trea­sury); the basis on which the funds would be dis­trib­uted to the pub­lic; man­ag­ing bank liq­uid­ity prob­lems (since though banks would not be made insol­vent by such a pol­icy, they would suf­fer sig­nif­i­cant drops in their income streams); and ensur­ing that the pro­gram did not sim­ply start another asset bubble.

Tam­ing the Finance Sector

Finance per­forms gen­uine, essen­tial ser­vices in a cap­i­tal­ist econ­omy when it lim­its itself to (a) pro­vid­ing work­ing cap­i­tal to non-financial cor­po­ra­tions; (b) fund­ing invest­ment and entre­pre­neur­ial activ­ity, whether directly or indi­rectly; © fund­ing hous­ing pur­chase for strictly res­i­den­tial pur­poses, whether to owner-occupiers for pur­chase or to investors for the pro­vi­sion of rental prop­er­ties; and (d) pro­vid­ing finance to house­holds for large expen­di­tures such as auto­mo­biles, home ren­o­va­tions, etc.

It is a destruc­tive force in cap­i­tal­ism when it pro­motes lever­aged spec­u­la­tion on asset or com­mod­ity prices, and funds activ­i­ties (like lev­ered buy­outs) that drive debt lev­els up and rely upon ris­ing asset prices for their suc­cess. Such activ­i­ties are the over­whelm­ing focus of the non-bank finan­cial sec­tor today, and are the pri­mary rea­son why finan­cial sec­tor debt has risen from triv­ial lev­els of below 10 per­cent of GDP before the 1970s to the peak of over 120 per­cent in early 2009.

Fig­ure 14

Return­ing cap­i­tal­ism to a finan­cially robust state must involve a dra­matic fall in the level of pri­vate debt—and the size of the finan­cial sec­tor— as well as poli­cies that return the finan­cial sec­tor to a ser­vice role to the real economy.

The size of the finan­cial sec­tor is directly related to the level of pri­vate debt, which in Amer­ica peaked at 303% of GDP in early 2009 (see Fig­ure 15). Using his­tory as our guide, Amer­ica will only return to being a finan­cially robust soci­ety when this ratio falls back to below 100% of GDP. Most other OECD coun­tries like­wise need to dras­ti­cally reduce their lev­els of pri­vate debt.

Fig­ure 15

The per­cent­age of total wages and prof­its earned by the FIRE sec­tor (as defined in the NIPA tables) gives another guide. America’s period of robust eco­nomic growth coin­cided with FIRE sec­tor prof­its being between 10 and 20 per­cent of total prof­its, and wages in the FIRE sec­tor being below 5 per­cent of total wages. Finance sec­tor prof­its peaked at over 50% of total prof­its in 2001, while wages in the FIRE sec­tor peaked at over 9 per­cent of total wages.

Fig­ure 16

Since finance sec­tor prof­its are pri­mar­ily a func­tion of the level of pri­vate debt, this implies that the level of debt needs to shrink by a fac­tor of 3–4, while employ­ment in the finance sec­tor needs to roughly halve. At the max­i­mum, the finance sec­tor should be no more than 50% of its cur­rent size.

Fig­ure 17

Such a large con­trac­tion in the size of the sec­tor means that the major­ity of those who cur­rently work there will need to find gain­ful employ­ment else­where. Indi­vid­u­als who can actu­ally eval­u­ate invest­ment proposals—generally speak­ing, engi­neers rather than finan­cial engineers—will need to be hired in their place. Many of the stan­dard prac­tices of that sec­tor today will have to be elim­i­nated or dras­ti­cally cur­tailed, while many prac­tices that have been largely aban­doned will have to be reinstated.

Tam­ing the Credit Accelerator

Capitalism’s crises have always been a prod­uct of the finan­cial sec­tor fund­ing spec­u­la­tion on asset prices rather than fund­ing busi­ness and inno­va­tion. This allows finan­cial sec­tor prof­its to grow far larger than is war­ranted, on the foun­da­tion of a far larger level of pri­vate debt than soci­ety can sup­port. This lend­ing causes a pos­i­tive feed­back loop between accel­er­at­ing debt and ris­ing asset prices, lead­ing to both a debt and asset price bub­ble. The asset price bub­ble must burst—because it relies upon accel­er­at­ing debt for its maintenance—but once it bursts, soci­ety is still left with the debt.

The under­ly­ing cause is the rela­tion­ship between debt and asset prices in a credit-based econ­omy. As I explain in numer­ous places (“A much more neb­u­lous con­cep­tion”, “Debunk­ing Macro­eco­nom­ics”), aggre­gate demand is the sum of income (Y) plus the change in debt , and this is expended on both newly pro­duced goods and ser­vices and buy­ing finan­cial claims on exist­ing assets—which I call “Net Asset Turnover” . At a very gen­eral level, this implies the fol­low­ing relationship:

Net Asset Turnover can be bro­ken down into the price index for assets , times their quan­tity , times the turnover —expressed as a frac­tion of the num­ber of assets

It there­fore fol­lows that there is a rela­tion­ship between the accel­er­a­tion of debt and change in asset prices.

Some accel­er­a­tion of debt is vital for a grow­ing econ­omy. As good empir­i­cal work by Fama and French has con­firmed (Fama and French 1999; Fama and French 2002), change in debt is the main source of funds for invest­ment, and as Schum­peter explains (Schum­peter 1934, pp. 95–107), the inter­play between invest­ment and the endoge­nous cre­ation of spend­ing power by the bank­ing sys­tem ensures that this will be a cycli­cal process. Debt accel­er­a­tion dur­ing a boom and decel­er­a­tion dur­ing a slump are thus essen­tial aspects of capitalism.

How­ever this rela­tion also implies that the accel­er­a­tion of debt is a fac­tor in the rate of change of asset prices (along with the change in income) and that when asset prices grow faster than incomes and con­sumer prices, the motive force behind it will be the accel­er­a­tion of debt. At the same time, the growth in asset prices is the major incen­tive to accel­er­at­ing debt: this is the pos­i­tive feed­back loop on which all asset bub­bles are based, and it is why they must ulti­mately burst (see Fig­ure 10 and Fig­ure 11). This is the foun­da­tion of Ponzi Finance (Min­sky 1982, p. 29), and it is this aspect of finance that has to be tamed to reduce the destruc­tive impact of finance on capitalism.

I do not believe that reg­u­la­tion alone will achieve this aim, for two reasons.

  • Minsky’s propo­si­tion that “sta­bil­ity is desta­bi­liz­ing” applies to reg­u­la­tors as well as to mar­kets. If reg­u­la­tions actu­ally suc­ceed in enforc­ing respon­si­ble finance, the rel­a­tive tran­quil­lity that results from that will lead to the belief that such tran­quil­lity is the norm, and the reg­u­la­tions will ulti­mately be abol­ished. After all, this is what hap­pened after the last Great Depression.
  • Banks profit by cre­at­ing debt, and they are always going to want to cre­ate more debt. This is sim­ply the nature of bank­ing. Reg­u­la­tions are always going to be attempt­ing to restrain this ten­dency, and in this strug­gle between an “immov­ably object” and an “irre­sistible force”, I have no doubt that the force will ulti­mately win.

If we rely on reg­u­la­tion alone to tame the finan­cial sec­tor, then it will be tamed while the mem­ory of the cri­sis it caused per­sists, only to be over­thrown by a resur­gent finan­cial sec­tor some decades hence (scep­tics on this point should take a close look at Fig­ure 2, show­ing the debt to GDP graph for Aus­tralia from 1860 till today).

There are thus only two options to limit capitalism’s ten­den­cies to finan­cial crises: to change the nature of either lenders or bor­row­ers in a fun­da­men­tal way. There are pro­pos­als for the for­mer, which I’ll dis­cuss later, but (for rea­sons I’ll dis­cuss now) my pref­er­ence is to address the lat­ter by reduc­ing the appeal of lever­aged spec­u­la­tion on asset prices.

There are, I believe, no prospects for fun­da­men­tally alter­ing the behav­iour of the finan­cial sec­tor because, as already noted, the key deter­mi­nant of prof­its in the finance sec­tor is the level of debt it can gen­er­ate. How­ever it is organ­ised and what­ever lim­its are put upon its behav­iour, it will want to cre­ate more debt.

There are prospects for alter­ing the behav­iour of the non-financial sec­tor towards debt because, fun­da­men­tally, debt is a bad thing for the bor­rower: the spend­ing power of debt now is an entice­ment, but with it comes the draw­back of ser­vic­ing debt in the future. For that rea­son, when either invest­ment or con­sump­tion is the rea­son for tak­ing on debt, bor­row­ers will be restrained in how much they will accept. Only when they suc­cumb to the entice­ment of lever­aged spec­u­la­tion will bor­row­ers take on a level of debt that can become sys­tem­i­cally dangerous.

This can eas­ily be illus­trated using dis­ag­gre­gated bor­row­ing data for Aus­tralia. At first glance, though per­sonal debt appears quite volatile, and strongly related to the busi­ness cycle—rising dur­ing booms and falling dur­ing slumps—there is clearly no trend across busi­ness cycles (see Fig­ure 18; “R90” refers to the start of the 1990s reces­sion, and “GFC” to the start of the cur­rent eco­nomic cri­sis for which Aus­tralians use the acronym “GFC”—or “Global Finan­cial Crisis”).

Fig­ure 18

How­ever there clearly is a trend in mort­gage debt across busi­ness cycles, and when rescaled by this trend, the volatil­ity of per­sonal debt is a non-event (see Fig­ure 19).

Fig­ure 19

The dif­fer­ence between the two series is obvi­ous. Regard­less of the end­less induce­ments from the finance sec­tor to enter into per­sonal debt, com­mit­ments by the pub­lic to per­sonal debt are gen­er­ally related to and reg­u­lated by income. Com­mit­ments to debt for the pur­chase of assets, on the other hand, are related not to income, but to expec­ta­tions of lever­aged prof­its on ris­ing asset prices—when the fac­tor most respon­si­ble for caus­ing growth in asset prices is accel­er­at­ing debt.

This rela­tion­ship between debt accel­er­a­tion and change in asset prices is espe­cially appar­ent for mort­gage debt. The R2 between mort­gage debt accel­er­a­tion and change in real house prices is 0.78 in the USA over 25 years, and 0.6 in Aus­tralia over 30 years (see Fig­ure 11 and Fig­ure 22). Though debt accel­er­a­tion can enable increased con­struc­tion or turnover , the far greater flex­i­bil­ity of prices, and the treat­ment of hous­ing as a vehi­cle for spec­u­la­tion rather than accom­mo­da­tion, means that the brunt of the accel­er­a­tion dri­ves house price appre­ci­a­tion. The same effect applies in the far more volatile share mar­ket: accel­er­at­ing debt leads to ris­ing asset prices, which encour­ages more debt acceleration.

Fig­ure 20

Fig­ure 21

The link between accel­er­at­ing debt lev­els and ris­ing asset prices is there­fore the basis of capitalism’s ten­dency to expe­ri­ence finan­cial crises. That link has to be bro­ken if finan­cial crises are to be made less likely—if not avoided entirely. This requires a rede­f­i­n­i­tion of finan­cial assets in such a way that the temp­ta­tions of Ponzi Finance can be eliminated.

Jubilee Shares

The key fac­tor that allows Ponzi Schemes to work in asset mar­kets is the “Greater Fool” promise that a share bought today for $1 can be sold tomor­row for $10. No inter­est rate, no reg­u­la­tion, can hold against the charge to insan­ity that such a fea­si­ble promise fer­ments, and on such a foun­da­tion the now almost for­got­ten folly of the Dot­Com Bub­ble was built. Both the promise and the folly are well illus­trated in Yahoo’s share price (see Fig­ure 22).

Fig­ure 22

I pro­pose the rede­f­i­n­i­tion of shares in such a way that the entice­ment of lim­it­less price appre­ci­a­tion can be removed, and the pri­mary mar­ket can take prece­dence over the sec­ondary mar­ket. A share bought in an IPO or rights offer would last for­ever (for as long as the com­pany exists) as now with all the rights it cur­rently con­fers. It could be sold once onto the sec­ondary mar­ket with all the same priv­i­leges. But on its next sale it would have a life span of 50 years, at which point it would terminate.

The objec­tive of this pro­posal is to elim­i­nate the appeal of using debt to buy exist­ing shares, while still mak­ing it attrac­tive to fund inno­v­a­tive firms or star­tups via the pri­mary mar­ket, and still mak­ing pur­chase of the share of an estab­lished com­pany on the sec­ondary mar­ket attrac­tive to those seek­ing an annu­ity income.

I can envis­age ways in which this basic pro­posal might be refined, while still main­tain­ing the pri­mary objec­tive of mak­ing lever­aged spec­u­la­tion on the price of exist­ing share unat­trac­tive. The ter­mi­na­tion date could be made a func­tion of how long a share was held; the num­ber of sales on the sec­ondary mar­ket before the Jubilee effect applied could be more than one. But the basic idea has to be to make bor­row­ing money to gam­ble on the prices of exist­ing shares a very unat­trac­tive proposition.

The Pill”

At present, if two indi­vid­u­als with the same sav­ings and income are com­pet­ing for a prop­erty, then the one who can secure a larger loan wins. This real­ity gives bor­row­ers an incen­tive to want to have the loan to val­u­a­tion ratio increased, which under­pins the finance sector’s abil­ity to expand debt for prop­erty purchases.

Since the accel­er­a­tion of debt dri­ves the rise in house prices, we get both the bub­ble and the bust. But since houses turn over much more slowly than do shares, this process can go on for a lot longer.

Fig­ure 23

The buildup of mort­gage debt there­fore also goes on for much longer (see Fig­ure 24 and Fig­ure 25).

Fig­ure 24

Fig­ure 25

Lim­its on bank lend­ing for mort­gage finance are obvi­ously nec­es­sary, but while those con­trols focus on the income of the bor­rower, both the lender and the bor­rower have an incen­tive to relax those lim­its over time. This relax­ation is in turn the fac­tor that enables a house price bub­ble to form while dri­ving up the level of mort­gage debt per head.

Fig­ure 26

I instead pro­pose bas­ing the max­i­mum debt that can be used to pur­chase a prop­erty on the income (actual or imputed) of the prop­erty itself. Lenders would only be able to lend up to a fixed mul­ti­ple of the income-earning capac­ity of the prop­erty being purchased—regardless of the income of the bor­rower. A use­ful mul­ti­ple would be 10, so that if a prop­erty rented for $30,000 p.a., the max­i­mum amount of money that could be bor­rowed to pur­chase it would be $300,000.

Under this regime, if two par­ties were vying for the same prop­erty, the one that raised more money via sav­ings would win. There would there­fore be a neg­a­tive feed­back rela­tion­ship between lever­age and house prices: an gen­eral increase in house prices would mean a gen­eral fall in leverage.

I call this pro­posal The Pill, for “Prop­erty Income Lim­ited Lever­age”. This pro­posal is a lot sim­pler than Jubilee Shares, and I think less in need of tin­ker­ing before it could be final­ized. Its real prob­lem is in the imple­men­ta­tion phase, since if it were intro­duced in a coun­try where the prop­erty bub­ble had not fully burst, it could cause a sharp fall in prices. It would there­fore need to be phased in slowly over time—except in a coun­try like Japan where the house price bub­ble is well and truly over (even though house prices are still falling).

There are many other pro­pos­als for reform­ing finance, most of which focus on chang­ing the nature of the mon­e­tary sys­tem itself. The best of these focus on insti­tut­ing a sys­tem that removes the capac­ity of the bank­ing sys­tem to cre­ate money via “Full Reserve Banking”.

Full Reserve Banking

The for­mer could be done by remov­ing the capac­ity of the pri­vate bank­ing sys­tem to cre­ate money. This is the sub­stance of the Amer­i­can Mon­e­tary Insti­tute’s pro­pos­als, which are now embod­ied in the National Emer­gency Employ­ment Defense Act of 2011 (HR 2990), a Bill which was sub­mit­ted to Con­gress by Con­gress­man Den­nis Kucinich on Sep­tem­ber 21st 2011. This bill would remove the capac­ity of the bank­ing sec­tor to cre­ate money, along the lines the the 100% reserve pro­pos­als first cham­pi­oned by Irv­ing Fisher dur­ing the Great Depres­sion (Fisher 1936), and vest the capac­ity for money cre­ation in the gov­ern­ment alone.

A sim­i­lar sys­tem is pro­posed by the UK’s New Eco­nomic Foun­da­tion with its Pos­i­tive Money proposal.

Tech­ni­cally, both these pro­pos­als would work. I won’t go into great detail on them here, other than to note my reser­va­tion about them, which is that I don’t see the bank­ing system’s capac­ity to cre­ate money as the causa cau­sans of crises, so much as the uses to which that money is put. As Schum­peter explains so well, the endoge­nous cre­ation of money by the bank­ing sec­tor gives entre­pre­neurs spend­ing power that exceeds that com­ing out of “the cir­cu­lar flow” alone. When the money cre­ated is put to Schum­peter­ian uses, it is an inte­gral part of the inher­ent dynamic of cap­i­tal­ism. The prob­lem comes when that money is cre­ated instead for Ponzi Finance rea­sons, and inflates asset prices rather than enabling the cre­ation of new assets.

My cau­tion with respect to full reserve bank­ing sys­tems is that this endoge­nous expan­sion of spend­ing power would become the respon­si­bil­ity of the State alone. Here, though I am a pro­po­nent of gov­ern­ment counter-cyclical spend­ing, I am scep­ti­cal about the capac­ity of gov­ern­ment agen­cies to get the cre­ation of money right at all times. This is not to say that the pri­vate sec­tor has done a bet­ter job—far from it! But the pri­vate bank­ing sys­tem will always be there—even if changed in nature—ready to exploit any slipups in gov­ern­ment behav­iour that can be used to jus­tify a return to the sys­tem we are cur­rently in. Slipups will surely occur, espe­cially if the new sys­tem still enables spec­u­la­tion on asset prices to occur.

Since in the real world, peo­ple for­get and die, the mem­ory of the chaos we are liv­ing through now won’t be part of the mind­set when those slipups occur, espe­cially if the end of the Age of Delever­ag­ing ush­ers in a period of eco­nomic tran­quil­lity like the 1950s. We could well have 100% money reforms “reformed” out of exis­tence once more.

Schum­peter­ian bank­ing also inher­ently includes the capac­ity to make mis­takes: to fund a ven­ture that doesn’t suc­ceed, and yet to be will­ing to take that risk again in the hope of fund­ing one that suc­ceeds spec­tac­u­larly. I am wary of the capac­ity of that mind­set to co-exist with the bureau­cratic one that dom­i­nates government.

So though I am not opposed to the 100% Reserve Bank­ing pro­posal, I am not enthu­si­as­tic either. I believe they need curbs on the capac­ity to finance asset price spec­u­la­tion like Jubilee Shares and The Pill, and if they have them, these alone might achieve most of what mon­e­tary reform­ers hope to achieve with far more exten­sive change to the finan­cial system.

Other issues

As Dou­glas Adams once bril­liantly remarked, most of our solu­tions to human prob­lems involve move­ments of small green pieces of paper, and my solu­tions clearly fall into that camp:

This planet has—or rather had—a prob­lem, which was this: most of the peo­ple liv­ing on it were unhappy for pretty much of the time. Many solu­tions were sug­gested for this prob­lem, but most of these were largely con­cerned with the move­ments of small green pieces of paper, which is odd because on the whole it wasn’t the small green pieces of paper that were unhappy. (Adams 1988)

I have said noth­ing here about Global Warm­ing and Peak Oil. Clearly these fac­tors will shape the post-Great Con­trac­tion world far more pow­er­fully than would my reforms. The rea­sons for not men­tion­ing them include specialisation—I am an econ­o­mist after all, not a spe­cial­ist on the cli­mate or energy—and the fact that these issues will ulti­mately make the finan­cial cri­sis look triv­ial by com­par­i­son. Dis­cussing them while dis­cussing the finan­cial cri­sis would have swamped the lat­ter topic almost entirely.

End­ing the dom­i­nance of the FIRE sec­tor will also expose the extent to which Amer­ica and the UK in par­tic­u­lar have been de-industrialised in the last 30 years. Though the relo­ca­tion of pro­duc­tion from the West­ern OECD to devel­op­ing nations could have occurred inde­pen­dently of the growth of Ponzi Finance, Ponzi Finance enabled this trend to go on for much longer than it could have oth­er­wise done. It is highly likely that reforms to end Ponzi Finance will be blamed for caus­ing the cri­sis in unem­ploy­ment that has in fact existed for decades, and would merely be exposed by sud­denly reduc­ing the size of the FIRE sector.

On the bright side

All of the above makes for bleak read­ing. I cer­tainly do expect a bleak future his­tory for humankind in most of the rest of this cen­tury, which I believe will bear out the pre­dic­tions first made by the “Lim­its to Growth” report in 1972 (Mead­ows, Ran­ders et al. 1972; Mead­ows, Mead­ows et al. 2005; Turner 2008).

Fig­ure 27: From Turner 2008. 2 solid cir­cle series rep­re­sent upper and lower bound esti­mates respec­tively

Despite this, I am a long term opti­mist for human­ity. We have a depress­ing ten­dency to learn about the unsus­tain­abil­ity of cumu­la­tive processes only after a cri­sis (Dia­mond 2005), but we also have an extra­or­di­nary intel­li­gence, and a species nature that val­ues empathy—along with our equally obvi­ous ten­dency to let hier­ar­chy and per­sonal gain take the ascen­dancy in human affairs. Ulti­mately I believe we’ll work out a means to live sus­tain­ably on this planet and, in the very dis­tant future, to live beyond it as well. But to do so, we have to under­stand our cur­rent sit­u­a­tion prop­erly. There is no chance to move towards a bet­ter future if we mis­un­der­stand the sit­u­a­tion we are cur­rently in. That’s why I keep on going.

In this work, I find myself fol­low­ing the lead of the physi­cist and applied math­e­mati­cian Pro­fes­sor John Blatt—a fel­low Aus­tralian (a Syd­neysider even!) whom I never met, but whose writ­ings were the foun­da­tion of my first for­ays into eco­nomic dynam­ics and complexity:

We close this intro­duc­tion with a philo­soph­i­cal point. Karl Marx said: “The philoso­phers hith­erto have only inter­preted the world in var­i­ous ways; the thing, how­ever, is to change it.” There have been many changes in the world since this was writ­ten… But only the fool­hardy could claim that these changes have all, or even mostly, been for the better.

It is not the task of this book to change the world. Let us try to under­stand just a small part of it, namely the dynam­ics of com­pet­i­tive cap­i­tal­ism. It is by no means cer­tain that the human race has a future at all. But if it does, that future can not be harmed, and may even be aided, by an hon­est attempt to under­stand our past. (Blatt 1983, p. 15)

Ref­er­ences

Adams, D. (1988). So Long, and Thanks for All the Fish.

Bean, C. (2010). “Joseph Schum­peter Lec­ture: The Great Mod­er­a­tion, the Great Panic, and the Great Con­trac­tion.” Jour­nal of the Euro­pean Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion
8(2–3): 289–325.

Benati, L. (2008). “The ‘Great Mod­er­a­tion’ in the United King­dom.” Jour­nal of Money, Credit, and Bank­ing
40(1): 121–147.

Bernanke, B. S. (2004). The Great Mod­er­a­tion: Remarks by Gov­er­nor Ben S. Bernanke At the meet­ings of the East­ern Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion, Wash­ing­ton, DC Feb­ru­ary 20, 2004. East­ern Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion. Wash­ing­ton, DC, Fed­eral Reserve Board.

Bernanke, B. S. (2004). Panel dis­cus­sion: What Have We Learned Since Octo­ber 1979? Con­fer­ence on Reflec­tions on Mon­e­tary Pol­icy 25 Years after Octo­ber 1979, St. Louis, Mis­souri, Fed­eral Reserve Bank of St. Louis.

Biggs, M. and T. Mayer (2010). “The Out­put Gap Conun­drum.” Intereconomics/Review of Euro­pean Eco­nomic Pol­icy
45(1): 11–16.

Biggs, M., T. Mayer, et al. (2010). “Credit and Eco­nomic Recov­ery: Demys­ti­fy­ing Phoenix Mir­a­cles.” SSRN eLi­brary.

Blatt, J. M. (1983). Dynamic eco­nomic sys­tems: a post-Keynesian approach. Armonk, N.Y, M.E. Sharpe.

Camp­bell, S. D. (2007). “Macro­eco­nomic Volatil­ity, Pre­dictabil­ity, and Uncer­tainty in the Great Mod­er­a­tion: Evi­dence from the Sur­vey of Pro­fes­sional Fore­cast­ers.” Jour­nal of Busi­ness and Eco­nomic Sta­tis­tics
25(2): 191–200.

Canova, F. (2009). “What Explains the Great Mod­er­a­tion in the U.S.? A Struc­tural Analy­sis.” Jour­nal of the Euro­pean Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion
7(4): 697–721.

D’Agostino, A. and K. Whe­lan (2008). “Fed­eral Reserve Infor­ma­tion dur­ing the Great Mod­er­a­tion.” Jour­nal of the Euro­pean Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion
6(2–3): 609–620.

Dia­mond, J. (2005). Col­lapse. How Soci­eties Choose to Fail or Suc­ceed. New York, Viking.

Fama, E. F. and K. R. French (1999). “The Cor­po­rate Cost of Cap­i­tal and the Return on Cor­po­rate Invest­ment.” Jour­nal of Finance
54(6): 1939–1967.

Fama, E. F. and K. R. French (2002). “Test­ing Trade-Off and Peck­ing Order Pre­dic­tions about Div­i­dends and Debt.” Review of Finan­cial Stud­ies
15(1): 1–33.

Fisher, I. (1933). “The Debt-Deflation The­ory of Great Depres­sions.” Econo­met­rica
1(4): 337–357.

Fisher, I. (1936). 100% money. New York, Adelphi.

G.I. (2011). Ser­ial Dis­ap­point­ment. The Econ­o­mist. Lon­don, The Economist.

Gali, J. and L. Gam­betti (2009). “On the Sources of the Great Mod­er­a­tion.” Amer­i­can Eco­nomic Jour­nal: Macro­eco­nom­ics
1(1): 26–57.

Gian­none, D., M. Lenza, et al. (2008). “Explain­ing the Great Mod­er­a­tion: It Is Not the Shocks.” Jour­nal of the Euro­pean Eco­nomic Asso­ci­a­tion
6(2–3): 621–633.

Hicks, J. (1981). “IS-LM: An Expla­na­tion.” Jour­nal of Post Key­ne­sian Eco­nom­ics
3(2): 139–154.

Hicks, J. R. (1935). “Wages and Inter­est: The Dynamic Prob­lem.” The Eco­nomic Jour­nal
45(179): 456–468.

Hicks, J. R. (1937). “Mr. Keynes and the “Clas­sics”; A Sug­gested Inter­pre­ta­tion.” Econo­met­rica
5(2): 147–159.

Hicks, J. R. (1939). Value and Cap­i­tal: an inquiry into some fun­da­men­tal prin­ci­ples of eco­nomic the­ory. Oxford, Oxford Uni­ver­sity Press.

Hud­son, M. (2000). “The Math­e­mat­i­cal Eco­nom­ics of Com­pound Inter­est: A 4,000-Year Overview.” Jour­nal of Eco­nomic Stud­ies
27(4–5): 344–363.

Hud­son, M. (2004). The Archae­ol­ogy of Money: Debt ver­sus Barter The­o­ries of Money’s Ori­gins. Credit and state the­o­ries of money: The con­tri­bu­tions of A. Mitchell Innes. L. R. Wray. Chel­tenham, U.K, Edward Elgar: 99–127.

Keen, S. (1995). “Finance and Eco­nomic Break­down: Mod­el­ing Minsky’s ‘Finan­cial Insta­bil­ity Hypoth­e­sis.’.” Jour­nal of Post Key­ne­sian Eco­nom­ics
17(4): 607–635.

Keen, S. (1996). “The Chaos of Finance: The Chaotic and Marx­ian Foun­da­tions of Minsky’s ‘Finan­cial Insta­bil­ity Hypoth­e­sis.’.” Economies et Soci­etes
30(2–3): 55–82.

Keen, S. (1997). “From Sto­chas­tics to Com­plex­ity in Mod­els of Eco­nomic Insta­bil­ity.” Non­lin­ear Dynam­ics, Psy­chol­ogy, and Life Sci­ences
1(2): 151–172.

Keen, S. (2000). The Non­lin­ear Eco­nom­ics of Debt Defla­tion. Com­merce, com­plex­ity, and evo­lu­tion: Top­ics in eco­nom­ics, finance, mar­ket­ing, and man­age­ment: Pro­ceed­ings of the Twelfth Inter­na­tional Sym­po­sium in Eco­nomic The­ory and Econo­met­rics. W. A. Bar­nett, C. Chiarella, S. Keen, R. Marks and H. Schn­abl. New York, Cam­bridge Uni­ver­sity Press: 83–110.

Keen, S. (2001). Debunk­ing eco­nom­ics: The naked emperor of the social sci­ences. Annan­dale Syd­ney & Lon­don UK, Pluto Press Aus­tralia & Zed Books UK.

Keen, S. (2005). Expert Opin­ion, Per­ma­nent Mort­gages vs Cooks. Syd­ney, Legal Aid NSW.

Keen, S. (2006). Steve Keen’s Monthly Debt Report Novem­ber 2006 “The Reces­sion We Can’t Avoid?”. Steve Keen’s Debt­watch. Syd­ney. 1: 21.

Keen, S. (2007). Deeper in Debt: Australia’s addic­tion to bor­rowed money. Occa­sional Papers. Syd­ney, Cen­tre for Pol­icy Development.

Keen, S. (2008). Keynes’s ‘revolv­ing fund of finance’ and trans­ac­tions in the cir­cuit. Keynes and Macro­eco­nom­ics after 70 Years. R. Wray and M. Forstater. Chel­tenham, Edward Elgar: 259–278.

Keen, S. (2010). “Solv­ing the Para­dox of Mon­e­tary Prof­its.” Eco­nom­ics: The Open-Access, Open Assess­ment E-Journal
4(2010–31).

Keen, S. (2011). Debunk­ing eco­nom­ics: The naked emperor dethroned? Lon­don, Zed Books.

Keen, S. (2011). “Debunk­ing Macro­eco­nom­ics.” Eco­nomic Analy­sis & Pol­icy
41(3): 147–167.

Keen, S. (2011). “A mon­e­tary Min­sky model of the Great Mod­er­a­tion and the Great Reces­sion.” Jour­nal of Eco­nomic Behav­ior & Orga­ni­za­tion
In Press, Cor­rected Proof.

Keynes, J. M. (1936). The gen­eral the­ory of employ­ment, inter­est and money. Lon­don, Macmillan.

Keynes, J. M. (1937). “The Gen­eral The­ory of Employ­ment.” The Quar­terly Jour­nal of Eco­nom­ics
51(2): 209–223.

Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1972). Econo­met­ric Test­ing of the Nat­ural Rate Hypoth­e­sis. The Econo­met­rics of Price Deter­mi­na­tion Con­fer­ence, Octo­ber 30–31 1970. O. Eck­stein. Wash­ing­ton, D.C., Board of Gov­er­nors of the Fed­eral Reserve Sys­tem and Social Sci­ence Research Coun­cil: 50–59.

Lucas, R. E., Jr. (2003). “Macro­eco­nomic Pri­or­i­ties.” Amer­i­can Eco­nomic Review
93(1): 1–14.

Mead­ows, D. H., D. Mead­ows, et al. (2005). Lim­its to growth : the 30-year update. Lon­don, Earthscan.

Mead­ows, D. H., J. Ran­ders, et al. (1972). The lim­its to growth. New York, Signet.

Min­sky, H. P. (1957). “Mon­e­tary Sys­tems and Accel­er­a­tor Mod­els.” The Amer­i­can Eco­nomic Review
47(6): 860–883.

Min­sky, H. P. (1982). Can “it” hap­pen again? : essays on insta­bil­ity and finance. Armonk, N.Y., M.E. Sharpe.

Muth, J. F. (1961). “Ratio­nal Expec­ta­tions and the The­ory of Price Move­ments.” Econo­met­rica
29(3): 315–335.

Obama, B. (2009). Obama’s Remarks on the Econ­omy. New York, New York Times.

Rein­hart, C. M. and K. S. Rogoff (2008). This Time is Dif­fer­ent: A Panoramic View of Eight Cen­turies of Finan­cial Crises, National Bureau of Eco­nomic Research, Inc, NBER Work­ing Papers: 13882.

Schum­peter, J. A. (1934). The the­ory of eco­nomic devel­op­ment : an inquiry into prof­its, cap­i­tal, credit, inter­est and the busi­ness cycle. Cam­bridge, Mass­a­chu­setts, Har­vard Uni­ver­sity Press.

Shafer, W. and H. Son­nen­schein (1993). Mar­ket demand and excess demand func­tions. Hand­book of Math­e­mat­i­cal Eco­nom­ics. K. J. Arrow and M. D. Intrili­ga­tor, Else­vier. 2: 671–693.

Son­nen­schein, H. (1973). “Do Wal­ras’ Iden­tity and Con­ti­nu­ity Char­ac­ter­ize the Class of Com­mu­nity Excess Demand Func­tions?” Jour­nal of Eco­nomic The­ory
6(4): 345–354.

Sraffa, P. (1960). Pro­duc­tion of com­modi­ties by means of com­modi­ties :pre­lude to a cri­tique of eco­nomic the­ory. Cam­bridge, Cam­bridge Uni­ver­sity Press.

Sum­mers, P. M. (2005). “What Caused the Great Mod­er­a­tion? Some Cross-Country Evi­dence.” Fed­eral Reserve Bank of Kansas City Eco­nomic Review
90(3): 5–32.

Turner, G. M. (2008). “A com­par­i­son of The Lim­its to Growth with 30 years of real­ity.” Global Envi­ron­men­tal Change
18(3): 397–411.

Turner, G. M., R. Hoff­man, et al. (2011). “A tool for strate­gic bio­phys­i­cal assess­ment of a national econ­omy — The Aus­tralian stocks and flows frame­work.” Envi­ron­men­tal Mod­el­ling & Soft­ware
In Press, Cor­rected Proof.

Wood­ford, M. (2009). “Con­ver­gence in Macro­eco­nom­ics: Ele­ments of the New Syn­the­sis.” Amer­i­can Eco­nomic Jour­nal: Macro­eco­nom­ics
1(1): 267–279.

Essen­tial Read­ings from Debtwatch

Finan­cial Instability

Rov­ing Cav­a­liers of Credit
Read Some Min­sky
Mon­e­tary Prof­its Para­dox
Are We “It” Yet?
Mon­e­tary Mul­ti­sec­toral Model

The New Depression

“No-one saw this com­ing”?
Why the Cri­sis is not over
Delever­ag­ing with a twist
Bernanke doesn’t under­stand the Great Depres­sion
The Case Against Bernanke

Aus­tralian Housing

Res­cu­ing the Bub­ble
Aus­tralian house prices
Com­pe­ti­tion No Panacea
House Prices & Banks I
House Prices & Banks II

Video overview

Lec­tures on Endoge­nous Money
Debt and Aus­tralian hous­ing
HARDtalk inter­view
INET Inter­view on why I saw “It” coming

48 Responses to Manifesto

  1. Pingback: Why Was The Great Recession So Great? - TheArmoTrader | TheArmoTrader

  2. Pingback: Rolling Jubilee: A Radical and Effective Solution to Abolishing Personal Debt | I Went Bankrupt

  3. Pingback: Republicans, Democrats, and Jobs | Socialist Agenda Webzine

  4. Pingback: UK economy: The radical options » Pickersleigh Community Watch

  5. Pingback: Budget 2013: Radical options for the UK economy | My Website

  6. Pingback: Budget 2013: Radical options for the UK economy | Next Buzz Media

  7. Peter Bearse says:

    Prof. Keen: Dr. Carmine Gorga and myself are try­ing to put together a ses­sion for the forth­com­ing (Jan., 2014) mtg. of the AEA on “Unortho­dox Mod­els of the Eco­nomic Sys­tem.” We will be pre­sent­ing papers on the Math­e­mat­ics, Geom­e­try, and Econo­met­rics of Con­cor­dian eco­nom­ics. Would you like to join our ses­sion as a pre­sen­ter, ref­eree, or panelist?

    I appre­ci­ate your insights and accom­plish­ments. More spe­cific com­ments will fol­low in due course.

    Mean­while, best wishes for the full suc­cess of your Kick­starter campaign.

    PETER BEARSE, Ph.D., Inter­na­tiona Con­sult­ing Econ­o­mist and author.

  8. Steve Keen says:

    Thanks Peter,

    I’d be happy to par­tic­i­pate, but as I am no longer funded by a Uni­ver­sity, my par­tic­i­pa­tion would be depen­dent on hav­ing my travel and accom­modaition costs covered.

    Please con­tact me via debunk­ing AT gmail DOT com so we can con­tinue the conversation.

  9. Brian Cevallos Fujiy says:

    Hello Prof. Steve Keen. I’m a under­grad­u­ate stu­dent from Peru and I just wanted to thank you for all the work and ded­i­ca­tion you pro­vide to this page. Right now I’m work­ing on my grad­u­at­ing essay about the causal rela­tions on debt and asset prices to explain the Two Lost Decades of Japan, with an attempt to pro­vide a dis­crete time dynamic model in the paper. Minsky’s, Fisher’s, Dillard’s and your work have been an enlight­ened jour­ney in con­trast with all the con­tents that stan­dard col­leges around the world doesn’t provide.

    Thank you and best wishes.

  10. Pingback: Deus Ex Imperium: Economic Instability and Political (Ir)reslience | Anechoic Echo Chamber

  11. Pingback: Austerity, balance, commonweal | It's Just a Jump to the Left, and then a Step to the Right

  12. Pingback: Debt Jubilee: Revolutionary change or reform to stabilize capitalism? « Systemic Disorder

  13. Pingback: An Historical Warning For Proponents Of A Modern Debt Jubilee | Barnaby Is Right

  14. Pingback: Why Full Reserve Banking Advocates Are Myopic | Barnaby Is Right

  15. Pingback: Weekly (weekly) | Southend-on-Sea in Transition

  16. Pingback: "The ideology of debt a powerful tool to justify violent inequalities"

  17. Pingback: The Multi-Trillion Dollar Question: How Much of Our Debt Is Odious? | Raging Bull-shit

  18. Pingback: Multi-Trillion Dollar Question: How Much Of Our Debt Is “Odious”? | Thought FTW

  19. Pingback: La dette sera-t-elle le catalyseur de la prochaine grande révolte ? - OuiShare

  20. Pingback: Regime Change Begins at Home | Liberate Britain

  21. Pingback: “La ideología de la deuda es una herramienta poderosa para justificar desigualdades violentas”[HD1] | Ability of Read

  22. Pingback: Steve Keen’s Manifesto | Survive - Prosper

  23. Pingback: My proposal for a game changing event on 7th May 2015 | Viral Democracy

Leave a Reply