It’s time to abolish negative gearing

Flattr this!

By Philip Soos

The Con­ver­sa­tion

Few Aus­tralian hous­ing poli­cies are more con­tentious than neg­a­tive gear­ing.

Despite the pub­lic­i­ty it has received and its pop­u­lar­i­ty with gov­ern­ment and prop­er­ty investors, lit­tle analy­sis of neg­a­tive gear­ing can be found with­in easy reach, with much of it acces­si­ble only in aca­d­e­m­ic jour­nals. Only an occa­sion­al frag­ment is found in the main­stream media.

Australia’s pol­i­cy on neg­a­tive gear­ing is con­sid­ered a sacred cow by investors and politi­cians, with Prime Min­is­ter Julia GillardTrea­sur­er Wayne Swan and Fed­er­al Hous­ing and Home­less­ness Min­is­ter Bren­dan O’Con­nor rul­ing out changes to this pol­i­cy. The rea­son for this obsti­na­cy is that neg­a­tive gear­ing allows a prop­er­ty investor to deduct loss­es against the investor’s per­son­al tax lia­bil­i­ty at their mar­gin­al tax rate (MTR), a tax-min­imi­sa­tion strat­e­gy adopt­ed by 1,110,922 tax­pay­ers who vote. Prop­er­ty is run at a net loss when inter­est pay­ments and prop­er­ty-relat­ed expens­es like repairs and main­te­nance exceed rental income.

The strong Aus­tralian econ­o­my has not expe­ri­enced a reces­sion since the ear­ly 1990s. This, along with reduced per­son­al tax bur­dens, real ris­ing incomes, exten­sive prop­er­ty sub­si­dies and tax breaks, and rapid increas­es in prop­er­ty val­ues, deliv­ered an eco­nom­ic envi­ron­ment con­ducive to neg­a­tive gear­ing. From 1996 to 2010, hous­ing prices surged by 130%, adjust­ed for infla­tion and qual­i­ty.

The present hous­ing and rental afford­abil­i­ty cri­sis is plac­ing tremen­dous finan­cial stress on many Aus­tralians as hous­ing and rental prices have out­paced wages, and pro­vid­ed the spark for the pub­lic to ques­tion the valid­i­ty of sub­si­dis­ing investors, whether they choose to gam­ble on mak­ing a return by sell­ing prop­er­ty at a high­er price or even­tu­al­ly becom­ing cash-flow pos­i­tive when rents rise to exceed out­go­ings.

Despite the fact that neg­a­tive gear­ing has exist­ed for a long time, much asser­tion but sur­pris­ing­ly lit­tle evi­dence has been made to jus­ti­fy this pol­i­cy across all class­es of invest­ment, whether it be shares, busi­ness, or prop­er­ty invest­ment. The sup­port­ers of neg­a­tive gear­ing pro­vide neg­li­gi­ble evi­dence to show that is it a sound pol­i­cy.

Deductibil­i­ty and tax min­imi­sa­tion under neg­a­tive gear­ing

It is com­mon sense that both busi­ness­es and investors should be allowed to deduct the costs direct­ly incurred in mak­ing an income, but labour is unable to do so. A salaried employ­ee incurs sub­stan­tial costs in the course of earn­ing a wage (for instance, accom­mo­da­tion, trav­el­ling to and from the work­place, and child­care) but gov­ern­ment pol­i­cy bars deduc­tion of these costs against wages.

There is a dou­ble stan­dard in oper­a­tion here. From a dis­tri­b­u­tion­al or equi­ty per­spec­tive, this pol­i­cy is biased towards thewealthy, as busi­ness and invest­ment cap­i­tal own­er­ship is con­cen­trat­ed into this class, which relies pro­por­tion­ate­ly less upon wages.

The dis­par­i­ty between wage earn­ers and investors is exac­er­bat­ed when neg­a­tive gear­ing is con­sid­ered. The net income loss from an invest­ment prop­er­ty reduces the investor’s per­son­al tax lia­bil­i­ty, even though that loss was gen­er­at­ed else­where. Earn­ing a wage and earn­ing income from an invest­ment are two sep­a­rate activ­i­ties and should be treat­ed as such. Busi­ness com­men­ta­tor Alan Kohler accu­rate­ly sum­marised the incon­sis­ten­cy between invest­ment and employ­ment:

Five years ago Trea­sur­er Peter Costel­lo told Aus­tralians: “Work for a liv­ing and we’ll tax you at close to 50 cents in the dol­lar; spec­u­late and we’ll only take 25 cents. Not only that but, as a spe­cial deal – while stocks last – we’ll pay half your spec­u­lat­ing costs.”

To sum up this line of rea­son­ing, investors are undu­ly advan­taged by the present tax­a­tion arrange­ments rel­a­tive to labour. Invest­ment cap­i­tal is over­whelm­ing­ly con­cen­trat­ed in the wealth­i­est house­holds, who deduct invest­ments costs against income gen­er­at­ed, have the high­est per­son­al incomes and thus MTRs, can deduct invest­ment loss­es against their per­son­al tax lia­bil­i­ty (neg­a­tive gear­ing), can car­ry for­ward loss­es and low­er their effec­tive MTRs.

Clear­ly, the tax sys­tem is biased towards the rich in terms of cost deduc­tion and tax lia­bil­i­ty min­imi­sa­tion. Some of this bias can be reduced by main­tain­ing con­sis­ten­cy: labour should be allowed to deduct costs against wages but dis­al­low neg­a­tive gear­ing for investors.

Increas­ing the rental stock and low­er­ing rents

This is the pri­ma­ry argu­ment in favour of neg­a­tive gear­ing: that it pro­vides an incen­tive to investors to pur­chase prop­er­ty for rent, thus increas­ing the sup­ply of rental prop­er­ties as a pro­por­tion of the total hous­ing stock. As the rea­son­ing goes, neg­a­tive gear­ing holds rental prices down, ben­e­fit­ing ten­ants.

The evi­dence shows oth­er­wise. 92% of res­i­den­tial prop­er­ty invest­ment is for the pur­chase of exist­ing dwellings rather than those new­ly con­struct­ed, mean­ing that for­mer own­er-occu­piers and ten­ants have to pur­chase or rent else­where, respec­tive­ly, thus result­ing in lit­tle to no net increase in the sup­ply of rental dwellings.

In the long term, it makes lit­tle sense for the sup­ply of rental prop­er­ties to increase com­pared to the total res­i­den­tial stock unless there is a pro­found upward swing in hous­ing prices, with investors spurred into the mar­ket on expec­ta­tions of mak­ing a sub­stan­tial prof­it through real­is­ing cap­i­tal gains upon sale. Accord­ing­ly, there is lit­tle incen­tive when long term data from Aus­tralia and oth­er coun­tries shows that hous­ing prices track infla­tion, despite numer­ous and ongo­ing booms and busts.

Neg­a­tive gear­ing is also bad­ly tar­get­ed as high-income pro­fes­sion­als and mil­lion­aires also alleged­ly receive low­er rents. If pol­i­cy­mak­ers are con­cerned about rental afford­abil­i­ty, there are oth­er options to pur­sue. The obvi­ous can­di­date is the Cen­tre­link Com­mon­wealth Rent Assis­tance (CRA) scheme, a sub­sidy pro­vid­ed to low-income ten­ants.

The effects of quar­an­ti­ning neg­a­tive gear­ing in the 1980s

The favourite scare sto­ry pro­mul­gat­ed by the hous­ing lob­by is that when the Hawke/Keating gov­ern­ment quar­an­tined neg­a­tive gear­ing dur­ing 1985–87, it caused rental prices to surge, quick­ly lead­ing to its rein­state­ment. For­tu­nate­ly, not only did the evi­dence refute this urban myth, it showed that neg­a­tive gear­ing can be safe­ly quar­an­tined, if not abol­ished.

Rents rose in Perth and Syd­ney only, remained steady in Mel­bourne and Can­ber­ra, and fell in Bris­bane, Ade­laide, Hobart and Dar­win. If the lob­by was cor­rect, quar­an­ti­ning should have adverse­ly affect­ed all cap­i­tal city rental mar­kets equal­ly, not just two out of eight (even when fac­tor­ing in a lagged response). There were con­found­ing fac­tors at work: ris­ing inter­est rates, intro­duc­tion of cap­i­tal gains tax and a stock mar­ket bub­ble.

Odd­ly enough, while the lob­by claims that quar­an­ti­ning will increase rents, the inverse is not con­sid­ered: rents have esca­lat­ed from 2006 onwards while neg­a­tive gear­ing was in effect. Per­haps they could claim that rents would have been high­er oth­er­wise. This, how­ev­er, is an ad infini­tum argu­ment; that is, neg­a­tive gear­ing is not gen­er­ous enough, so by increas­ing the scope of tax deductibil­i­ty, it can serve to fur­ther con­strain rents.

How much does neg­a­tive gear­ing cost?

ATO data pro­vides an esti­mate of the cost of neg­a­tive gear­ing. In 1993–94 it was $850 mil­lion, fluc­tu­at­ing around the $1 bil­lion mark over the next sev­er­al years. As investors piled into the mar­ket, the cost rapid­ly esca­lat­ed to a peak of $3.8 bil­lion in 2007-08 before falling to $2.9 bil­lion in 2009-10. Over the last sev­en­teen years, neg­a­tive gear­ing has cost tax­pay­ers an infla­tion-adjust­ed $33.5 bil­lion (2012 dol­lars).

What to do?

Pol­i­cy out­comes can be enhanced by quar­an­ti­ning neg­a­tive gear­ing deduc­tions to the pur­chase of new­ly con­struct­ed prop­er­ties, but not for estab­lished prop­er­ties. It would be even bet­ter to remove it, as it makes lit­tle sense to sub­sidise prop­er­ty investors, regard­less of the rea­sons for invest­ment when there are bet­ter poli­cies for help­ing low-income ten­ants.

Also, the neg­a­tive gear­ing debate pre­sup­pos­es the exis­tence of income tax­a­tion, which has no jus­ti­fi­ca­tion when evi­dence sug­gests that sub­stan­tial amounts of tax rev­enue can be raised from far more effi­cient bases. Pro­duc­tive indi­vid­u­als and busi­ness already bear the brunt of income tax, which is mere­ly one of 125 bur­den­some tax­es.

Accord­ing to the prop­er­ty lob­by, it’s too dan­ger­ous to reform neg­a­tive gear­ing, let alone abol­ish it. For­tu­nate­ly, there’s no require­ment for any­one to believe the lob­by, giv­en the weight of evi­dence against their asser­tions and the fact that they have enough con­flicts of inter­est to fill a book.

Also read — Land Primer by Philip Soos
 

If you are inter­est­ed in more dis­cus­sions about this and sim­i­lar sub­jects, check out my site, Debunk­ing Eco­nom­ics here. SK

 

Bookmark the permalink.

About Steve Keen

I am Professor of Economics and Head of Economics, History and Politics at Kingston University London, and a long time critic of conventional economic thought. As well as attacking mainstream thought in Debunking Economics, I am also developing an alternative dynamic approach to economic modelling. The key issue I am tackling here is the prospect for a debt-deflation on the back of the enormous private debts accumulated globally, and our very low rate of inflation.