Debtwatch No 34: The Confidence Trick

flattr this!

"And, at this point, con­fi­dence is what it is all about… The first thing is to main­tain some con­fi­dence in our­selves and the prospects for our coun­try over time… Unfor­tu­nately, there is no lever marked ‘con­fi­dence’  that policy-makers can take hold of. Our task is very much one of seek­ing to behave, across the board, in ways that will fos­ter, rather than erode, con­fi­dence.  It is such con­fi­dence that, more than any­thing else, will help to drive us along the road to recov­ery.” (Glenn Stevens, April 21st 2009)

I fancy that over-confidence sel­dom does any great harm except when, as, and if, it beguiles its vic­tims into debt.” (Irv­ing Fisher, 1933)

In his recent speech “The Road To Recov­ery”, Australia’s Reserve Bank Gov­er­nor Glenn Stevens used “the C word” 17 times–versus, for exam­ple, 15 uses of the “R” word (“reces­sion”). The mes­sage was clearly that, if only we can all be con­fi­dent, then the other “R” word (“recovery”–which received ten men­tions) will surely occur.

Another promi­nent econ­o­mist who had the same atti­tude at the out­break of a finan­cial cri­sis was Irv­ing Fisher. Speak­ing to a bankers con­fer­ence just two days before the Great Crash of 1929, Fisher argued that mar­ket down­turns were caused by a “lunatic fringe”. Once they had exited, the bull mar­ket of the pre­ced­ing years would resume:

There is a cer­tain lunatic fringe in the stock mar­ket, and there always will be when­ever there is any suc­cess­ful bear move­ment going on… they will put the stocks up above what they should be and, when fright­ened, … will imme­di­ately want to sell out… when it is finally rid of the lunatic fringe, the stock mar­ket will never go back to 50 per cent of its present level…

We shall not see very much fur­ther, if any, reces­sion in the stock mar­ket, but rather … a resump­tion of the bull mar­ket, not as rapidly as it has been in the past, but still a bull rather than a bear move­ment.”  (Fisher 1929)

Fisher’s con­fi­dence led him to hang on to his margin-financed stocks (worth over $100 mil­lion in 2000-dollar terms). Despite his con­fi­dence, the stock mar­ket con­tin­ued its plunge from its peak of 31.3 in July 1929 to the nadir of 4.77 in May of 1932, while unem­ploy­ment rose from zero to 25 per­cent. Fisher was wiped out finan­cially, and left to pon­der how he could have got the behav­iour of the mar­ket, and the econ­omy, so badly wrong.

Three years later, he reached the con­clu­sion that he had been mis­led by two core ele­ments of the neo­clas­si­cal the­ory he had helped build: the beliefs that the econ­omy was always in equi­lib­rium, and that the debt com­mit­ments bor­row­ers had entered into to pur­chase finan­cial assets were based on cor­rect fore­casts of future eco­nomic prospects.

On equi­lib­rium, he rea­soned, even if it were true that the econ­omy tended towards equi­lib­rium, ran­dom events alone would ensure that all eco­nomic vari­ables were either above or below their equi­lib­rium lev­els. There­fore eco­nomic the­ory had to be about dis­e­qui­lib­rium rather than equilibrium:

The­o­ret­i­cally there may be— in fact, at most times there must be—  over– or under-production, over– or under-consumption, over– or under spend­ing, over– or under-saving, over– or under-investment, and over or under every­thing else. It is as absurd to assume that, for any long period of time, the vari­ables in the eco­nomic orga­ni­za­tion, or any part of them, will “ stay put,”  in per­fect equi­lib­rium, as to assume that the Atlantic Ocean can ever be with­out a wave.” (Fisher 1933)

This real­i­sa­tion in turn put paid to any notion that today’s debt com­mit­ments were based on an accu­rate pre­dic­tion of tomorrow’s eco­nomic out­comes. Instead, he iden­ti­fied over-indebtedness as one of the two key causes of Great Depression:

two dom­i­nant fac­tors [are …] over-indebtedness to start with and defla­tion fol­low­ing soon after… these two eco­nomic mal­adies, the debt dis­ease and the price-level dis­ease, are, in the great booms and depres­sions, more impor­tant causes than all oth­ers put together.

Thus over-investment and over-speculation are often impor­tant; but they would have far less seri­ous results were they not con­ducted with bor­rowed money. That is, over-indebtedness may lend impor­tance to over-investment or to over-speculation.

The same is true as to over-confidence. I fancy that over-confidence sel­dom does any great harm except when, as, and if, it beguiles its vic­tims into debt.” (Fisher 1933)

One would hope that eco­nomic the­ory had learnt from the Great Depres­sion, and in par­tic­u­lar from Fisher’s insights. Unfor­tu­nately, eco­nom­ics was eager to unlearn these lessons, because the very phe­nom­e­non of a Depres­sion was anath­ema to a pro­fes­sion that had always sought to eulo­gise the mar­ket econ­omy, rather than to under­stand it. Equi­lib­rium came back again in the guise of the “Neoclassical-Keynesian syn­the­sis” in the 1950s. By the 1990s, all ves­tiges of Keynes had been thrown away–and noth­ing of Fisher had been even assim­i­lated in the first place (sker­ricks of his thought are per­co­lat­ing through now though: see The Econ­o­mist for a pretty good overview of Fisher).

Today, macro­eco­nomic mod­els like TRYM (the TReasurY Macro­eco­nomic model that is used to pre­pare the Aus­tralian Fed­eral Bud­get) pre­sume that the econ­omy tends towards a “long run equi­lib­rium”. The appar­ent dynam­ics such mod­els dis­play are sim­ply the con­ver­gence of the model from an ini­tial start­ing point to the assumed long run equilibrium.

For exam­ple, the fig­ure below shows the TRYM model’s pre­dic­tions for unem­ploy­ment from March 1995 till March 2010 (Fig­ure 10: Dynamic Adjust­ment towards Steady State — Unem­ploy­ment; Mod­el­ling Sec­tion, Macro­eco­nomic Analy­sis Branch, Com­mon­wealth Trea­sury, The Macro­eco­nom­ics Of The Trym Model Of The Aus­tralian Econ­omy,  Com­mon­wealth of Aus­tralia 1996). The model “pre­dicted” that unem­ploy­ment would fall from around 9 per­cent in 1995 to just below 7 per­cent in 2010, sim­ply on the basis that unem­ploy­ment was assumed to con­verge to an a long run equi­lib­rium rate of 7 per­cent over time (the actual level fell well below this, and the  assumed equi­lib­rium unem­ploy­ment rate–the “NAIRU”–was there­fore later reduced to 5.25 percent).

Vir­tu­ally every­one knows Keynes’s quip that “in the long run we are all dead”. Yet very few realise that Keynes’s tar­get was pre­cisely this approach to eco­nomic modelling–of assum­ing that the econ­omy would sim­ply tend to return to equi­lib­rium after any disturbance:

But this long run is a mis­lead­ing guide to cur­rent affairs. In the long run we are all dead. Econ­o­mists set them­selves too easy, too use­less a task if in tem­pes­tu­ous sea­sons they can only tell us that when the storm is long past the ocean is flat again.”   (Keynes, 1923)

Hob­bled by this naive belief in equi­lib­rium, the eco­nom­ics pro­fes­sion was as unpre­pared for today’s cri­sis as it had been for the Great Depres­sion. Now that the cri­sis is well and truly with us, all con­ven­tional “neo­clas­si­cal” econ­o­mists can offer is the hope that the cri­sis can be over­come by a good, strong dose of confidence.

From Fisher’s point of view, such a belief is futile. In an econ­omy with an exces­sive level of debt and low infla­tion, he argued that con­fi­dence was irrelevant–and in fact dan­ger­ously mis­lead­ing, as he knew from painful per­sonal expe­ri­ence. Given over-indebtedness and low lev­els of infla­tion, a “chain reac­tion” would occur in which: 

(1) Debt liq­ui­da­tion leads to dis­tress sell­ing and to

(2) Con­trac­tion of deposit cur­rency, as bank loans are paid off, and to a slow­ing down of veloc­ity of cir­cu­la­tion. This con­trac­tion of deposits and of their veloc­ity, pre­cip­i­tated by dis­tress sell­ing, causes

(3) A fall in the level of prices, in other words, a swelling of the dol­lar. Assum­ing, as above stated, that this fall of prices is not inter­fered with by refla­tion or oth­er­wise, there must be

(4) A still greater fall in the net worths of busi­ness, pre­cip­i­tat­ing bank­rupt­cies and

(5) A like fall in prof­its, which in a “ cap­i­tal­is­tic,”  that is, a private-profit soci­ety, leads the con­cerns which are run­ning at a loss to make

(6) A reduc­tion in out­put, in trade and in employ­ment of labor. These losses, bank­rupt­cies, and unem­ploy­ment, lead to

(7) Pes­simism and loss of con­fi­dence, which in turn lead to

(8) Hoard­inq and slow­ing down still more the veloc­ity of circulation.The above eight changes cause

(9) Com­pli­cated dis­tur­bances in the rates of inter­est, in par­tic­u­lar, a fall in the nom­i­nal, or money, rates and a rise in the real, or com­mod­ity, rates of inter­est.” (Fisher 1933; The Debt Defla­tion The­ory of Great Depres­sions)

One key phe­nom­e­non that Fisher empha­sised was that defla­tion could make the debt bur­den worse even as bor­row­ers reduced their nom­i­nal debt levels–something I have termed “Fisher’s Para­dox”. In Fisher’s words:

Each dol­lar of debt still unpaid becomes a big­ger dol­lar, and if the over-indebtedness with which we started was great enough, the liq­ui­da­tion of debts can­not keep up with the fall of prices which it causes.

In that case, the liq­ui­da­tion defeats itself. While it dimin­ishes the num­ber of dol­lars owed, it may not do so as fast as it increases the value of each dol­lar owed.

Then, the very effort of indi­vid­u­als to lessen their bur­den of debts increases it, because of the mass effect of the stam­pede to liq­ui­date in swelling each dol­lar owed. Then we have the great para­dox which, I sub­mit, is the chief secret of most, if not all, great depressions:

The more the debtors pay, the more they owe. The more the eco­nomic boat tips, the more it tends to tip. It is not tend­ing to right itself, but is capsizing.”

This is a “dis­e­qui­lib­rium” phe­nom­e­non par excel­lence, because not only does it occur out of equi­lib­rium, it actu­ally dri­ves the sys­tem fur­ther from equi­li­bium. And it is indeed what hap­pened dur­ing the Great Depres­sion: America’s debt to GDP ratio rose even as nom­i­nal debt lev­els were reduced. The debt ratio rose from 175 at the end of 1929 to 235 per­cent in 1932, even as nom­i­nal pri­vate debt fell from US$163 bil­lion to US$134 billion.

Even though the public’s ini­tial attempt to reduce its debt bur­den was foiled, the reduc­tion in debt nonethe­less did have an impact: it drove the econ­omy into Depres­sion. In the credit-driven real world in which we live, aggre­gate demand is the sum of GDP plus the change in debt. The public’s attempt to reduce debt meant that the reduc­tions in debt sub­stan­tially reduced demand, and this delever­ag­ing was the unstop­pable force that made the Great Depres­sion “great”.

As the next chart shows, dur­ing the Roar­ing Twen­ties, the annual increase in debt was respon­si­ble for up to ten per­cent of aggre­gate demand. But when the Great Crash brought this period of lever­aged spec­u­la­tion to an end, the delever­ag­ing that Fisher described meant that the change in debt started to reduce from demand–and at its peak, the reduc­tion in debt in 1932 reduced aggre­gate demand by 25 percent.

As is obvi­ous, unem­ploy­ment sky­rock­eted as aggre­gate demand col­lapsed. When debt reaches the sky high lev­els it did before the Great Depres­sion, delever­ag­ing becomes the dom­i­nant force deter­min­ing the level of unemployment–but obvi­ously there is a lag. Unem­ploy­ment is the clas­sic “lag­ging indi­ca­tor”, because firms take time to respond to a drop in demand, firstly by ceas­ing to hire new work­ers and then by sack­ing exist­ing ones.

When work­ing with annual data at the time of the Great Depres­sion, this lag appears to be about one and a half years. Apply­ing that lag to the period from mid-1929 till mid-1938 (when Gov­ern­ment spend­ing and arma­ments pro­duc­tion for the loom­ing war in Europe started to boost demand and caused unem­ploy­ment to fall), the cor­re­la­tion between debt’s con­tri­bu­tion to demand and unem­ploy­ment was –0.85. The change in debt’s con­tri­bu­tion to demand thus explains 85 per­cent of the unem­ploy­ment expe­ri­ence of the Great Depression.

This is not good news for us today, for three rea­sons. Firstly, debt lev­els today are far higher than they were prior to the Great Depression–the force of delever­ag­ing is thus likely to be greater now than it was in the 1930s. Sec­ondly, given this higher level of debt, the cor­re­la­tion between the debt-financed pro­por­tion of aggre­gate demand and unem­ploy­ment is even stronger now than it was dur­ing the Great Depres­sion. Thirdly, given the greater depen­dence on debt today than ever before, and the social changes that have gone with the Ponz­i­fi­ca­tion of Cap­i­tal­ism, the lag between a fall in the debt-financed com­po­nent of demand and a rise in unem­ploy­ment has dropped to just two months.

The change in debt is there­fore the best–and most ominous–predictor of future unem­ploy­ment lev­els. Though well down from the peak level of being respon­si­ble for 25% of aggre­gate demand, pri­vate debt is still gen­er­at­ing 10 per­cent of demand in the USA. Yet even with still pos­i­tive debt-financed demand, unem­ploy­ment has risen to 8.7 per­cent. If delever­ag­ing results in debt reduc­ing aggre­gate demand by 25 per­cent as it did in the Great Depres­sion, then unem­ploy­ment is going to go much, much higher.

The same analy­sis applies to Aus­tralia. Since the cri­sis has yet to hit Aus­tralia as strongly as it has the USA or Europe, the belief that “we are different”–which I call “Kan­ga­roo Eco­nom­ics” in hon­our of our national fauna–is still preva­lent here. So too is the belief that, if we do suf­fer a reces­sion, it will be due to exter­nal forces rather than to our own eco­nomic circumstances.

The data begs to dif­fer. Though our aggre­gate debt level didn’t reach Yan­kee heights–our peak debt to GDP level was about 165%, ver­sus 290% in the USA before defla­tion started–our rate of growth of debt was much higher, so that at its peak the growth in debt was respon­si­ble for 22% of aggre­gate demand. Now that debt is start­ing to fall, unem­ploy­ment is start­ing to rise. There is every rea­son to expect delever­ag­ing in Aus­tralia to drive unem­ploy­ment well into dou­ble digits.

So con­fi­dence is not “all it is about”: con­fi­dence played its role over the last thirty years as it “beguiled its vic­tims into debt”, in Fisher’s evoca­tive phrase. We don’t need more of it now, so much as less of it back then–but of course, we can’t amend history.

The vic­tims of past over­con­fi­dence include Cen­tral Bankers, whose res­cues of the finan­cial sys­tem sim­ply encour­aged it to search out a new group of poten­tial bor­row­ers to replace those who had already been debt-saturated. They were vic­tims of debt, as much as were the bor­row­ers, because the naive the­ory of eco­nom­ics they fol­lowed ignored the role of debt com­pletely. They there­fore couldn’t see the process that was lead­ing to cri­sis, even as their inter­ven­tions egged that process on to heights that it could never have reached with­out them.

Had Greenspan and his equiv­a­lents around the world not inter­vened in 1987, it is quite pos­si­ble that we would have expe­ri­enced a mild Depres­sion back then–mild because debt was only equiv­a­lent to 1929 lev­els then, because a larger Gov­ern­ment sec­tor than in the 1920s would have coun­ter­bal­anced the pri­vate sec­tor down­turn, and because higher infla­tion in the late 80s would have helped reduced the real bur­den of debt.

Now we are sit­ting on the precipice of a moun­tain of debt twice as high as in the Great Depres­sion, with low infla­tion turn­ing into defla­tion as Fisher warned, and with Cen­tral Bankers who do not have a clue why the econ­omy has sud­denly gone from “the Great Mod­er­a­tion” to “the Great­est Cri­sis Since the Great Depression”.

Over-confidence in the face of ris­ing debt did beguile us dur­ing the long boom. Con­fi­dence in the face of delever­ag­ing will not save us dur­ing the com­ing Depression.

END OF COMMENTARY

Com­ments on the Aus­tralian Data

Debt lev­els in Aus­tralia are very close to falling in nom­i­nal terms, and in fact only mort­gage debt is still ris­ing: both busi­ness and per­sonal debt (other than mort­gages) have fallen in the last few months. It is con­ceiv­able that, were it not for the “First Home Buy­ers Boost”, mort­gage debt as well would be falling now too (the scheme is more aptly described as the “First Home Ven­dors Boost”, since prices at the low end of the mar­ket have been dri­ven up by far more than the $7,000 increase in the grant).

As a result, the debt to GDP ratio has fallen for the last four months–though this is to some extent masked by Australia’s prac­tice of sum­ming the pre­vi­ous four quar­ters of GDP data to derive annual GDP, ver­sus the Amer­i­can prac­tice of sim­ply mul­ti­ply­ing the cur­rent quarter’s GDP fig­ure by 4. Using the Aus­tralian approach, our debt to GDP ratio is now 160%; using the Amer­i­can, it is 162%, since GDP fell by 0.5% in the pre­vi­ous quarter.

Whichever way you cut it, delever­ag­ing is now well and truly under­way, and unem­ploy­ment will there­fore rise dra­mat­i­cally in the next few months. Most neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists are pre­dict­ing 7.5% unem­ploy­ment by mid-2010; I expect it will have entered dou­ble fig­ures by early in 2010.

Table One

Table Two

Bookmark the permalink.

212 Responses to Debtwatch No 34: The Confidence Trick

  1. Joe B says:

    Regard­ing stats such as CPI, unem­ploy­ment, and money sup­ply being mis­stated, check out John Williams’ (the econ­o­mist, not the com­poser) Shadow Stats:
    http://www.shadowstats.com/

    While he only cov­ers US stats, the same analy­sis could pos­si­bly be applied to Aussie stats.

  2. mannfm11 says:

    Infla­tion causes defla­tion. Social­ism isn’t a solu­tion. The oppo­nents of the Fed­eral reserve in the 1910 era men­tioned over and over again how the CB would cre­ate an infla­tion. Most of us believe that is merely a change in price, but it is an expan­sion in credit and money equiv­a­lents cre­ated by banks. The idea that Amer­i­can debt is an Amer­i­can prob­lem misses the point. The entire Asian boom was financed on US credit, the exten­tion of which allowed China to boom, access resources, etc. From what I have been able to gather, in the 1920’s, Wall Street financed a lot of export paper to facil­i­tate exports to Europe. This paper went bad. It isn’t so much the repay­ment of debt as the ceas­ing of cre­at­ing more debt that trig­gers the defla­tion, but I sus­pect the end game of try­ing to avoid this prob­lem is a collapse.

  3. Steve Keen says:

    Agree with you here mannfm11, on the issue of where the China boom came from. It was financed by Amer­i­can debt–the oppo­site of the way the neo­clas­si­cals inter­pret it, that excess Chi­nese sav­ings were then lent to Amer­i­cans. And ditto on the cause of the turn to deflation.

  4. The Outback Oracle says:

    Vir­tu­ally every month for the last 6 months, Trea­sury have been revis­ing down their esti­mates for per­for­mance of the econ­omy for the next 12 months i.e. get­ting it wrong every month. Now they are able, with absolute cer­tainty, to tell us what growth rates will be with absolute cer­tainty for the next 10 years!!! As Steve says “Yeah right!”

    Ken Henry jus­ti­fied the pre­dic­tions in his speech yes­ter­day. Fair dinkum, does it take a whole over­paid Dept to repro­duce a graph from the 1960’s and say “this is the future”. What do they do all day? Drink tea? Henry should resign and donate all his Super­an­nu­a­tion to those who have lost all their sav­ings through his, either, stu­pid­ity, or delib­er­ate lying over the past two years.

    Fur­ther, watch­ing Late­line last night it is appar­ent that Ken Henry still has not noticed a sin­gle dif­fer­ence between this reces­sion those that have gone before.
    Glen Stevens is just still singing the same ‘spin’ tune he instructed all the other “experts” to sing a month ago. Mind you, watch­ing Glen’s face, and care­fully weigh­ing his words, I don’t think he was too happy about pub­licly back­ing these Trea­sury GDP estimates!!!!

    On another note, I attended the Post Bud­get talk given by Bill Evans of West­pac in Bris­bane. I was pre­pared to rip his ears off for his stu­pid pre­dic­tions over the past two years. He beat me to the punch by putting up his pre­dic­tions of ear­lier years and com­par­ing them to real­ity. His pre­dic­tions and real­ity had noth­ing in com­mon! Inter­est­ingly, Bill put up our For­eign Debt lev­els and informed the audi­ence we are in the worst sit­u­a­tion in the world other than Ice­land, which has col­lapsed, and NZ which is on the verge.
    He did not expand on the dif­fi­cul­ties this is going to cause going for­ward, par­tic­u­larly with our Govt try­ing to finance it’s deficits in the com­ing years. He was scar­ing the audi­ence enough already, I think, and, as I have become aware over a long period, most peo­ple don’t even know that For­eign Debt exists or that there is such a thing as a Cur­rent Accout. So it is a bit dif­fi­cult to sud­denly raise it, and explain the sig­nif­i­cance in a few short min­utes, dur­ing a speech about the Bud­get.
    Nev­er­the­less, he is the first one of the MSM ‘experts’ I have seen to pub­licly acknowl­edge there is a seri­ous prob­lem there. I thought it was significant.

  5. BrightSpark1 says:

    g’day Out­back Oracle

    It looks like Bill Evans has had a “boat to Ice­land” moment, too bad it took him 33 er sorry 50 years too long. He has beaten all the oth­ers to this real­i­sa­tion however.

    I too saw Henry and Stevens on the TV last night and I tend to agree that Stevens was prob­a­bly wish­ing that he was some­where else.
    Only neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists could make claims like that and have the MSM broad­cast the garbage.

    Did you see Simon Crean crow­ing about how close he is to a free trade agree­ment with China? China which has pegged its cur­rency at least 1000% too high! He is pleased that the Chi­nese want to “invest” in Aus­tralia! He wants Aus­tralians to invest in China. “Yeah right” who brought him?

    We can’t pro­duce real prod­ucts for our own con­sump­tion, they have destroyed that capa­bil­ity. We need to bor­row at least $40,000,000,000 pa to cover the CAD (it has fallen from the pre­vi­ous year), and the gov­ern­ment is tak­ing on this bur­den aswell as bank for­eign debt rollovers by qui­etly issu­ing trea­sury notes (this self cen­sored by the MSN).
    If the econ­omy did “recover” what­ever that might mean, will we still be able to sell these notes on the for­eign mar­ket to keep the show on the road I think not. It would have been inter­est­ing to ask Stevens and Henry to explain where the for­eign credit would be com­ming from in the future, but then again “loose lips sink ships er dodgy economies”.

  6. MrT says:

    Jim

    Sorry about the very long delay in my reply.

    It seems like I had a shocker!! China’s Non per­form­ing Loans are now noth­ing like the 40% I quoted, they now claim about 1.6%. Sorry the 40% came from a link I clicked on while read­ing a cur­rent arti­cle but took me to one that was over 10yrs old. The Chi­nese have already taken all this off their books or put them in a “spe­cial invest­ment vehicle”.

  7. Pingback: Why the Government’s Attempt to Instill False Confidence Will Backfire « Truth11

  8. Pingback: Anarchistas » Defliacin?s kredito kriz?s mechanika

  9. Pingback: Guest Post: The Economy Will Not Recover Until Trust is Restored « naked capitalism

  10. Pingback: The Economy Will Not Recover Until Trust is Restored | Froogalizer.com

  11. Pingback: The Economy Will Not Recover Until Trust is Restored | FedUpUSA

  12. Pingback: The Economy Will Not Recover Until Trust is Restored - Washington's Blog

Leave a Reply