Bernanke an Expert on the Great Depression??

flattr this!

Note: This post has been modified ni the light of comments that the initial version quoted Bernanke out of context.

A link to this blog from a US legal advisory website the Practising Law Institute's In Brief ( "DEFLATION IN THE REAL WORLD”) reminded me of  Bernanke’s book Essays on the Great Depres­sion, which I’ve been aware of for some time but have yet to read. I’ll make amends on that front early this year; for­tu­nately, an extract from Chap­ter One is avail­able as a pre­view on the Prince­ton site (I couldn’t locate the promised eBook any­where!; in what fol­lows, when I quote Bernanke it is from the orig­i­nal jour­nal paper pub­lished in 1995, rather than this chapter).

To put it mildly, Bernanke’s analy­sis is not promising.

The most glar­ing prob­lem on first glance is that, despite Bernanke’s claim in Chap­ter One “THE MACROECONOMICS OF THE GREAT DEPRESSION: A Com­par­a­tive Approach” that he will sur­vey “our cur­rent under­stand­ing of the Great Depres­sion”, there is only a brief, twisted ref­er­ence to Irv­ing Fisher’s Debt Defla­tion The­ory of Great Depres­sions, and no dis­cus­sion at all of Hyman Minsky’s con­tem­po­rary Finan­cial Insta­bil­ity Hypoth­e­sis (and a blog­ger informed me that his entire ref­er­ence to Min­sky in the book amounted to one dis­cus­sion and one foot­note, which I’ll get to later on).

While he does dis­cuss Fisher’s the­ory, he pro­vides only a par­ody of it–in which he nonethe­less notes that Fisher’s pol­icy advice was influential:

Fisher envi­sioned a dynamic process in which falling asset and com­mod­ity prices cre­ated pres­sure on nom­i­nal debtors, forc­ing them into dis­tress sales of assets, which in turn led to fur­ther price declines and finan­cial dif­fi­cul­ties. His diag­no­sis led him to urge Pres­i­dent Roo­sevelt to sub­or­di­nate exchange-rate con­sid­er­a­tions to the need for refla­tion, advice that (ulti­mately) FDR followed.

He then explains that neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists in gen­eral read­ily dis­missed Fisher’s the­ory, for rea­sons that are very instructive:

Fisher’s idea was less influ­en­tial in aca­d­e­mic cir­cles, though, because of the coun­ter­ar­gu­ment that debt-deflation rep­re­sented no more than a redis­tri­b­u­tion from one group (debtors) to another (cred­i­tors). Absent implau­si­bly large dif­fer­ences in mar­ginal spend­ing propen­si­ties among the groups, it was sug­gested, pure redis­tri­b­u­tions should have no sig­nif­i­cant macro­eco­nomic effects. ” (Bernanke 1995, p. 17)

Bernanke him­self does try to make sense of Fisher within a neo­clas­si­cal frame­work, which I’ll get to below; but the gen­eral neo­clas­si­cal reac­tion to Fisher that he describes is a per­fect exam­ple of the old (and very apt!) joke that an econ­o­mist is some­one who, hav­ing heard that some­thing works in prac­tice, then ripostes “Ah! But does it work in theory?”.

It is also–I’m sorry, there’s just no other word for it–mind-numbingly stu­pid. A debt-deflation trans­fers income from debtors to cred­i­tors? From, um, peo­ple who default on their mort­gages to the peo­ple who own the mortgage-backed secu­ri­ties, or the banks?

Well then, put your hands up, all those cred­i­tors who now feel sub­stan­tially bet­ter off cour­tesy of our con­tem­po­rary debt-deflation…

What??? No-one? But surely you can see that in the­ory

The only way that I can make sense of this non­sense is that neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists assume that an increase in debt means a trans­fer of income from debtors to cred­i­tors (equal to the ser­vic­ing cost of the debt), and that this has no effect on the econ­omy apart from redis­trib­ut­ing income from debtors to cred­i­tors. So ris­ing debt is not a problem.

Sim­i­larly, a debt-deflation then means that cur­rent nom­i­nal incomes fall, rel­a­tive to accu­mu­lated debt that remains con­stant. This increases the real value of inter­est pay­ments on the debt, so that a debt-deflation also causes a trans­fer from debtors to creditors–though this time in real (inflation-adjusted) terms.

Do I have to spell out the prob­lem here? Only to neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists, I expect: dur­ing a debt-deflation, debtors don’t pay the inter­est on the debt–they go bank­rupt. So debtors lose their assets to the cred­i­tors, and the cred­i­tors get less–losing both their inter­est pay­ments and large slabs of their prin­ci­pal, and get­ting no or dras­ti­cally deval­ued assets in return. Nobody feels bet­ter off dur­ing a debt-deflation (apart from those who have accu­mu­lated lots of cash before­hand). Both debtors and cred­i­tors feel and are poorer, and the prob­lem of non-payment of inter­est and non-repayment of prin­ci­pal often makes cred­i­tors com­par­a­tively worse off than debtors (just ask any of Bernie Madoff’s ex-clients).

Back to Bernanke’s take on Fisher, rather than the generic neo­clas­si­cal idiocy on debt-deflation. Firstly, Bernanke’s “sum­mary” of Fisher’s argu­ment starts with asset price defla­tion: “Fisher envi­sioned a dynamic process in which falling asset and com­mod­ity prices cre­ated pres­sure on nom­i­nal debtors…”.

Sorry Ben, but (to use a bit of crude Aus­tralian ver­nac­u­lar), this is an “arse about tit” read­ing of Fisher.  Fisher’s dynamic process began with exces­sive debt, not with falling asset prices. You have con­fused cause and effect in Fisher’s the­ory: exces­sive debt and the delever­ag­ing process that engen­dered lead to falling asset and com­mod­ity prices as symp­toms (which then amplify the ini­tial prob­lem of exces­sive debt in a pos­i­tive feed­back process). To make this con­crete, Fisher referred to:

two dom­i­nant fac­tors, namely over-indebtedness to start with and defla­tion fol­low­ing soon after” (Fisher 1933, p. 341)

I hope that’s clear enough that, in Fisher’s argu­ment, overindebt­ed­ness is the first fac­tor and defla­tion the second–and in fact, Fisher argues that overindebt­ed­ness causes defla­tion, if the ini­tial rate of infla­tion is low enough (he also coun­te­nances the sit­u­a­tion in which infla­tion is higher and defla­tion doesn’t even­tu­ate, which he argues won’t lead to a Depres­sion). Before I dis­cuss Bernanke’s own attempt to express what his mis­in­ter­pre­ta­tion of Fisher in neo­clas­si­cal form, it’s worth set­ting Fisher’s own causal sequence out in full. In his Econo­met­rica paper, Fisher argued that the process that leads to a Depres­sion is the following:

(1) Debt liq­ui­da­tion leads to dis­tress sell­ing and to

(2) Con­trac­tion of deposit cur­rency, as bank loans are paid off, and to a slow­ing down of veloc­ity of cir­cu­la­tion. This con­trac­tion of deposits and of their veloc­ity, pre­cip­i­tated by dis­tress sell­ing, causes

(3) A fall in the level of prices, in other words, a swelling of the dol­lar. Assum­ing, as above stated, that this fall of prices is not inter­fered with by refla­tion or oth­er­wise, there must be

(4) A still greater fall in the net worths of busi­ness, pre­cip­i­tat­ing bank­rupt­cies and

(5) A like fall in prof­its, which in a “cap­i­tal­is­tic,” that is, a private-profit soci­ety, leads the con­cerns which are run­ning at a loss to make

(6) A reduc­tion in out­put, in trade and in employ­ment of labor. These losses, bank­rupt­cies, and unem­ploy­ment, lead to

(7) Pes­simism and loss of con­fi­dence, which in turn lead to

(8) Hoard­ing and slow­ing down still more the veloc­ity of cir­cu­la­tion. The above eight changes cause

(9) Com­pli­cated dis­tur­bances in the rates of inter­est, in par­tic­u­lar, a fall in the nom­i­nal, or money, rates and a rise in the real, or com­mod­ity, rates of inter­est.” (Econo­met­rica, 1933, Vol­ume 1, p. 342)

(Check this pre­vi­ous blog entry for more on this topic)

In its own way, this is a very sim­ple process to both under­stand and to model. To under­stand it, all we have to do is look at the cur­rent eco­nomic sit­u­a­tion in the USA–all nine stages of Fisher’s process are already well under way there. I’ve also mod­elled the debt com­po­nent of this process in my papers on finan­cial insta­bil­ity (and the defla­tion aspect too in other research I’ve yet to pub­lish, but which will be in my forth­com­ing book for Edward Elgar, Finance and Eco­nomic Break­down [expected pub­li­ca­tion date is 2011]).

So why didn’t Bernanke–and other neo­clas­si­cal economists–understand Fisher’s expla­na­tion and develop it?

Because an essen­tial aspect of Fisher’s rea­son­ing was the need to aban­don the fic­tion that a mar­ket econ­omy is always in equilibrium.

The notion that a mar­ket econ­omy is in equi­lib­rium at all times is of course absurd: if it were true, prices, incomes–even the state of the weather–would always have to be “just right” at all times, and there would be no eco­nomic news at all, because the news would always be that “every­thing is still per­fect”. Even neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists implic­itly acknowl­edge this by the way they analyse the impact of tar­iffs for exam­ple, by show­ing to their stu­dents how, by increas­ing prices, tar­iffs drive the sup­ply above the equi­lib­rium level and drive the demand below it.

The rea­son neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists cling to the con­cept of equi­lib­rium is that, for his­tor­i­cal rea­sons, it has become a dom­i­nant belief within that school that one can only model the econ­omy if it is assumed to be in equilibrium.

From the per­spec­tive of real sciences–and of course engineering–that is sim­ply absurd. The econ­omy is a dynamic sys­tem, and like all dynamic sys­tems in the real world, it will be nor­mally out of equi­lib­rium. That is not a bar­rier to math­e­mat­i­cally mod­el­ling such sys­tems however–one sim­ply has to use “dif­fer­en­tial equa­tions” to do so. There are also many very sophis­ti­cated tools that have been devel­oped to make this much eas­ier today–largely sys­tems engi­neer­ing and con­trol the­ory tech­nol­ogy (such as Simulink, Vis­sim, etc.)–than it was cen­turies ago when dif­fer­en­tial equa­tions were first developed.

Some neo­clas­si­cals are aware of this tech­nol­ogy, but in my expe­ri­ence, it’s a tiny minority–and the major­ity of bog stan­dard neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists aren’t even aware of dif­fer­en­tial equa­tions (they under­stand dif­fer­en­ti­a­tion, which is a more lim­ited but foun­da­tional math­e­mat­i­cal tech­nique). They believe that if a process is in equi­lib­rium over time, it can be mod­elled, but if it isn’t, it can’t. And even the “high priests” of eco­nom­ics, who should know bet­ter, stick with equi­lib­rium mod­el­ling at almost all times.

Equi­lib­rium has thus moved from being a tech­nique used when econ­o­mists knew no bet­ter and had no tech­nol­ogy to han­dle out of equi­lib­rium phenomena–back when Jevons, Wal­ras and Mar­shall were devel­op­ing what became neo­clas­si­cal eco­nom­ics in the 19th cen­tury, and thought that com­par­a­tive sta­t­ics would be a tran­si­tional method­ol­ogy prior to the devel­op­ment of truly dynamic analy­sis –into an “arti­cle of faith”. It is as if it is a denial of all that is good and fair about cap­i­tal­ism to argue that at any time, a mar­ket econ­omy could be in dis­e­qui­lib­rium with­out that being the fault of bungling gov­ern­ments or nasty trade unions and the like.

And so to this day, the pin­na­cle of neo­clas­si­cal eco­nomic rea­son­ing always involves “equi­lib­rium”. Lead­ing neo­clas­si­cals develop DSGE (“Dynamic Sto­chas­tic Gen­eral Equi­lib­rium”) mod­els of the econ­omy. I have no problem–far from it!–with mod­els that are “Dynamic”, “Sto­chas­tic”, and “Gen­eral”. Where I draw the line is “Equi­lib­rium”. If their mod­els were to be truly Dynamic, they should be “Dis­e­qui­lib­rium” models–or mod­els in which whether the sys­tem is in or out of equi­lib­rium at any point in time is no hin­drance to the mod­el­ling process.

Instead, with this fix­a­tion on equi­lib­rium, they attempt to analyse all eco­nomic processes in a hypo­thet­i­cal free mar­ket econ­omy as if it is always in equilibrium–and they do like­wise to the Great Depression.

Before the Great Depres­sion, Fisher made the same mis­take. His most notable con­tri­bu­tion (for want of a bet­ter word!) to eco­nomic the­ory was a model of finan­cial mar­kets as if they were always in equi­lib­rium.

Fisher was in some senses a pre­de­ces­sor of Bernanke: though he was never on the Fed­eral Reserve, he was America’s most renowned aca­d­e­mic econ­o­mist dur­ing the early 20th cen­tury. He ruined his rep­u­ta­tion for aeons to come by also being a news­pa­per pun­dit and cheer­leader for the Roar­ing Twen­ties stock mar­ket boom (and he ruined his for­tune by putting his money where his mouth was and tak­ing out huge mar­gin loan posi­tions on the back of the con­sid­er­able wealth he earned from invent­ing the Rolodex).

Chas­tened and effec­tively bank­rupted, he turned his mind to work­ing out what on earth had gone wrong, and after about three years he came up with the best expla­na­tion of how Depres­sions occur (prior to Minsky’s bril­liant blend­ing of Marx, Keynes, Fisher and Schum­peter in hisFinan­cial Insta­bil­ity Hypoth­e­sis [here’s another link to this paper]). 

Prior to this life-altering expe­ri­ence how­ever, as a faith­ful neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mist, Fisher por­trayed the mar­ket for loans as essen­tially no dif­fer­ent from any other mar­ket in neo­clas­si­cal thought: it con­sisted of inde­pen­dent sup­ply of and demand func­tions, and a price mech­a­nism that set the rate of inter­est by equat­ing these two functions–thus putting the mar­ket into a state of equilibrium.

How­ever even with this abstrac­tion, he had to admit that there were two dif­fer­ences between the “mar­ket for loan­able funds” and a stan­dard com­mod­ity mar­ket: firstly that the loan­able fund mar­ket involves com­mit­ments over time, whereas in stan­dard neo­clas­si­cal mythol­ogy, com­mod­ity mar­kets are barter mar­kets where pay­ment and deliv­ery take place instan­ta­neously; and sec­ondly, it is unde­ni­able that some­times peo­ple don’t live up to those com­mit­ments over time–they go bankrupt.

Fisher dealt with these dif­fer­ences in the time-honoured neo­clas­si­cal man­ner: he assumed them away. He imposed two con­di­tions on his models:

“(A) The mar­ket must be cleared—and cleared with respect to every inter­val of time. (B) The debts must be paid.” ( Irv­ing Fisher, 1930, The The­ory of Inter­est. New York: Kel­ley & Mill­man p. 495)

Fisher did dis­cuss some prob­lems with these assump­tions, but in keep­ing with the neo­clas­si­cal delu­sion that one couldn’t model processes out of equi­lib­rium, these prob­lems didn’t lead to a revi­sion of his model.

Of course, if Fisher had been a real­ist, he would have admit­ted to him­self that a model that pre­sumes the econ­omy is always in equi­lib­rium will be a mis­lead­ing guide to the behav­iour of the actual econ­omy. But instead, as seems to hap­pen to all devo­tees of neo­clas­si­cal eco­nom­ics, he began to see his model as the real world–and used it to explain the Stock Mar­ket bub­ble of the 1920s as not due to “irra­tional exu­ber­ance”, but due to the won­der­ful work­ings of a mar­ket econ­omy in equilibrium.

Since Wall Street was also assumed to be in equi­lib­rium, stock prices were jus­ti­fied. And he defended the bub­ble as rep­re­sent­ing a real improve­ment in the liv­ing stan­dards of Amer­i­cans, because: 

We are now apply­ing sci­ence and inven­tion to indus­try as we never applied it before. We are liv­ing in a new era, and it is of the utmost impor­tance for every busi­ness­man and every banker to under­stand this new era and its impli­ca­tions… All the resources of mod­ern sci­en­tific chem­istry, met­al­lurgy, elec­tric­ity, are being utilized–for what? To make big incomes for the peo­ple of the United States in the future, to add to the div­i­dends of cor­po­ra­tions which are han­dling these new inven­tions, and nec­es­sar­ily, there­fore, to raise the prices of stocks which rep­re­sent shares in these new inven­tions.” (Fisher, Octo­ber 23rd 1929, in a speech to a bankers’ association)

Have you heard that one before: a “new era”? If I had a dol­lar for every time I saw that twad­dle used to jus­tify com­pa­nies with neg­a­tive earn­ings hav­ing sky­high val­u­a­tions dur­ing the Inter­net Bubble…

Fisher even dis­missed the 6% fall in the stock mar­ket that had occurred in the day before his speech as due to “a cer­tain lunatic fringe in the stock mar­ket, and there always will be when­ever there is any suc­cess­ful bear move­ment going on… they will put the stocks up above what they should be and, when fright­ened, … will imme­di­ately want to sell out.” 

The future, he told the assem­bled bankers, was rosy indeed:

Great pros­per­ity at present and greater pros­per­ity in view in the future … rather than spec­u­la­tion … explain the high stock mar­kets, and when it is finally rid of the lunatic fringe, the stock mar­ket will never go back to 50 per cent of its present level… We shall not see very much fur­ther, if any, reces­sion in the stock mar­ket, but rather … a resump­tion of the bull mar­ket, not as rapidly as it has been in the past, but still a bull rather than a bear move­ment.” (Fisher 1929)

Prior to this speech, he had made his fate­fully wrong pre­dic­tion on the future course of the Dow Jones in the New York Times. For the record, his state­ment was:

Stock prices have reached what looks like a per­ma­nently high plateau. I do not feel that there will soon, if ever, be a fifty or sixty point break below present lev­els, such as Mr. Bab­son has pre­dicted. I expect to see the stock mar­ket a good deal higher than it is today within a few months.”

Well, so much for all that. The stock mar­ket crash con­tin­ued for three years, unem­ploy­ment blew out from lit­er­ally zero (as recorded by the National Bureau of Eco­nomic Research) to 25 per­cent, America’s GDP col­lapsed, prices fell… the Great Depres­sion occurred.

At first, Fisher was com­pletely flum­moxed: he had no idea why it was hap­pen­ing, and blamed “spec­u­la­tors” for the fall (though not of course for the rise!) of the mar­ket, lack of con­fi­dence for its con­tin­u­ance, and so on… But expe­ri­ence ulti­mately proved a good if painful teacher, when he devel­oped “the Debt-Deflation The­ory of Great Depressions”.

An essen­tial aspect of this new the­ory was the aban­don­ment of the con­cept of equilibrium.

In his paper, he began by say­ing that:

We may ten­ta­tively assume that, ordi­nar­ily and within wide lim­its, all, or almost all, eco­nomic vari­ables tend, in a gen­eral way, to ward a sta­ble equi­lib­rium. In our class­room expo­si­tions of sup­ply and demand curves, we very prop­erly assume that if the price, say, of sugar is above the point at which sup­ply and demand are equal, it tends to fall; and if below, to rise.

How­ever, in the real world:

New dis­tur­bances are, humanly speak­ing, sure to occur, so that, in actual fact, any vari­able is almost always above or below the ideal equilibrium.

There­fore in the­ory as well as in real­ity, dis­e­qui­lib­rium must be the rule:

The­o­ret­i­cally there may be—in fact, at most times there must be— over– or under-production, over– or under-consumption, over– or under spend­ing, over– or under-saving, over– or under-investment, and over or under every­thing else. It is as absurd to assume that, for any long period of time, the vari­ables in the eco­nomic orga­ni­za­tion, or any part of them, will “stay put,” in per­fect equi­lib­rium, as to assume that the Atlantic Ocean can ever be with­out a wave.” (Fisher 1933, p. 339; empha­sis added)

He then con­sid­ered a range of “usual sus­pects” for crises–the ones often put for­ward by so-called Marx­ists such as “over-production”, “under-consumption”, and the like, and that favourite for neo­clas­si­cals even today, of blam­ing “under-confidence” for the slump. Then he deliv­ered his intel­lec­tual (and per­sonal) coup de grâce:

I ven­ture the opin­ion, sub­ject to cor­rec­tion on sub­mis­sion of future evi­dence, that, in the great booms and depres­sions, each of the above-named fac­tors has played a sub­or­di­nate role as com­pared with two dom­i­nant fac­tors, namely over-indebtedness to start with and defla­tion fol­low­ing soon after; also that where any of the other fac­tors do become con­spic­u­ous, they are often merely effects or symp­toms of these two. In short, the big bad actors are debt dis­tur­bances and price– level disturbances.

While quite ready to change my opin­ion, I have, at present, a strong con­vic­tion that these two eco­nomic mal­adies, the debt dis­ease and the price-level dis­ease (or dol­lar dis­ease), are, in the great booms and depres­sions, more impor­tant causes than all oth­ers put together…

Thus over-investment and over-speculation are often impor­tant; but they would have far less seri­ous results were they not con­ducted with bor­rowed money. That is, over-indebtedness may lend impor­tance to over-investment or to over-speculation.

The same is true as to over-confidence. I fancy that over-confidence sel­dom does any great harm except when, as, and if, it beguiles its vic­tims into debt. (Fisher 1933, pp. 340–341. Emphases added.)

From this point on, he elab­o­rated his the­ory of the Great Depres­sion which had as its essen­tial start­ing points the propo­si­tions that debt was above its equi­lib­rium level and that the rate of infla­tion was low. Start­ing from this posi­tion of dis­e­qui­lib­rium, he described the 9 step chain reac­tion shown above.

Of course, if the econ­omy had been in equi­lib­rium to begin with, the chain reac­tion could never have started. By pre­vi­ously fool­ing him­self into  believ­ing that the econ­omy was always in equi­lib­rium, he, the most famous Amer­i­can econ­o­mist of his day, com­pletely failed to see the Great Depres­sion coming.

How about Bernanke today? Well, as Mark Twain once said, his­tory doesn’t repeat, but it sure does rhyme. Just four years ago, as a Gov­er­nor of the Fed­eral Reserve, Bernanke was an enthu­si­as­tic con­trib­u­tor to the “debate” within neo­clas­si­cal eco­nom­ics that the global econ­omy was expe­rien­ing “The Great Mod­er­a­tion”, in which the trade cycle was a thing of the past–and he con­grat­u­lated the Fed­eral Reserve and aca­d­e­mic econ­o­mists in gen­eral for this suc­cess, which he attrib­uted to bet­ter mon­e­tary policy:

In the remain­der of my remarks, I will pro­vide some sup­port for the “improved-monetary-policy” expla­na­tion for the Great Moderation.”

Good call Ben. We have now moved from “The Great Mod­er­a­tion!” to “The Great Depres­sion?” as the debat­ing topic du jour.

On that front, his analy­sis of what caused the Great Depres­sion cer­tainly doesn’t imbue con­fi­dence. This chap­ter (first pub­lished in 1995 in the neo­clas­si­cal Jour­nal of Money Credit and Bank­ing [ Feb­ru­ary 1995, v. 27, iss. 1, pp. 1–28]–the same year my Min­skian model of Great Depres­sions was pub­lished in the non-neoclassical Jour­nal of Post Key­ne­sian Eco­nom­ics [Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 607–635]) con­sid­ers sev­eral pos­si­ble causes:

  • A neo­clas­si­cal, laboured re-working of Fisher’s debt-deflation hypoth­e­sis, to inter­pret it as a prob­lem of “agency”–“Intuitively, if a bor­rower can con­tribute rel­a­tively lit­tle to his or her own project and hence must rely pri­mar­ily on exter­nal finance, then the borrower’s incen­tives to take actions that are not in the lender’s inter­est may be rel­a­tively high; the result  is both dead­weight losses (for exam­ple, inef­fi­ciently high risk-taking or low effort) and the neces­sity of costly infor­ma­tion pro­vi­sion and mon­i­tor­ing)” (p. 17);
  • Aggre­gate demand shocks from the return to the Gold Stan­dard and its effect on world money sup­plies; and
  • Aggre­gate sup­ply shocks from the fail­ure of nom­i­nal wages to fall–“The link between nom­i­nal wage adjust­ment and aggre­gate sup­ply is straight­for­ward: If nom­i­nal wages adjust imper­fectly, then falling price lev­els raise real wages; employ­ers respond by cut­ting their work­forces” (p. 21).

None of these “causes” includes exces­sive pri­vate debt–the phe­nom­e­non that I hope now even Ben Bernanke can see was the cause of the Great Depression–and the rea­son why he and neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists like him are no longer dis­cussing “The Great Moderation”.

Whle they were doing that, a minor­ity of economists–myself included–were avidly devel­op­ing both Fisher and Minsky’s the­o­ries of Great Depres­sions. We are known gen­er­ally as “Post Key­ne­sian” econ­o­mists, and there Min­sky is an intel­lec­tual hero.  And how did Ben han­dle Min­sky? I have yet to read all of the Essays, but a blog­ger who has made the fol­low­ing comment:

In the entire vol­ume (Bernanke, ‘Essays on Great Depres­sion’, 2000, Prince­ton) there is a sin­gle refence to Min­sky in Part Two, page 43 — “Hyman Min­sky (1977) and Car­les Kindle­berger (1978) have … argued for the inher­ent insta­bil­ity of the finan­cial sys­tem but in doing so have had to depart from the assump­tion of ratio­nal eco­nomic behav­iour.” A foot­note adds — “I do not deny the pos­si­ble impor­tance of irra­tional­ity in eco­nomic life; how­ever it seems that the best research strat­egy is to push the ratio­nal­ity pos­tu­late as far as it will go.”

No need for any comment!!!!!!!

Indeed! Hav­ing not prop­erly com­pre­hended the best con­tem­po­rary expla­na­tion of the Great Depres­sion, and dis­missed the best mod­ern expla­na­tion because it didn’t make an assump­tion that neo­clas­si­cal econ­o­mists insist upon,  Bernanke is now trapped repeat­ing his­tory (inci­den­tally, this com­ment by Bernanke also gives the lie to the “assump­tions don’t mat­ter, it’s only the results that count” non­sense that Fried­man dished up as neo­clas­si­cal eco­nomic methodology–neoclassical econ­o­mists in fact care des­per­ately about their assump­tions and are will­ing to dis­miss rival the­o­ries sim­ply because they don’t make the same assump­tions, regard­less of how accu­rate they are). It is painfully obvi­ous that the real cause of this cur­rent finan­cial cri­sis was the exces­sive build-up of debt dur­ing pre­ced­ing spec­u­la­tive manias dat­ing back to the mid-1980s. The real dan­ger now is that, on top of this debt moun­tain, we are start­ing to expe­ri­ence the slip­pery slope of falling prices.

In other words, the cause of our cur­rent finan­cial cri­sis is debt com­bined with deflation–precisely the forces that Irv­ing Fisher described as the causes of the Great Depres­sion back in 1933.

About Steve Keen

I am a professional economist and a long time critic of conventional economic thought. As well as attacking mainstream thought in Debunking Economics, I am also developing an alternative dynamic approach to economic modelling. The key issue I am tackling here is the prospect for a debt-deflation on the back of the enormous debts accumulated in Australia, and our very low rate of inflation.
Bookmark the permalink.

54 Responses to Bernanke an Expert on the Great Depression??

  1. ken says:

    See the inter­view with Beranke linked to from http://www.ecu.edu/cs-educ/econ/parkerr.cfm

    Bernanke has more recently blamed the Fed­eral Reserve for rais­ing inter­est rates too high. As we’ve seen this time at high lev­els of debt the sys­tem is extremely unsta­ble and it is impos­si­ble to get inter­est rates cor­rect, the econ­omy is either in fast for­ward or fast reverse and once it switches noth­ing seems to do much.

  2. gordon says:

    Nice piece, Steve. I enjoyed it, thanks.

    Hav­ing said that, how­ever, as a non-economist I remain totally per­plexed by the Dis­ci­pline. By my under­stand­ing, sci­en­tific knowl­edge advances usu­ally in incre­men­tal steps, over time, with many con­trib­u­tors. Thus while some sci­en­tific dis­cov­er­ies may have rep­re­sented quan­tum leaps that smashed the preva­lent par­a­digm, with the devel­op­ment of the new par­a­digm the orig­i­nal pro­po­nent fades into the back­ground; to be revered, per­haps, but no longer cited.

    Thus while few con­tem­po­rary papers on nuclear par­ti­cles would take quo­ta­tions from Ruther­ford or Bohr, for exam­ple, it seems to me that much writ­ing on eco­nom­ics appears more like stud­ies of medieval or Eliz­a­bethan Eng­lish where every word writ­ten on The Green Man or by Shake­speare is care­fully parsed and analysed. [I do appre­ci­ate that your writ­ing here is edu­ca­tional in a lay sense and putting Bernanke’s com­ments into his­tor­i­cal per­spec­tive, so this is not a per­sonal crit­i­cism; but almost every­thing I read cites either Fisher (both pre– and post– 1930), Keynes (espe­cially) or von Mises as though nobody had done any­thing since.]

    On the other side there are model builders who use fairly sim­ple math­e­mat­ics to devise extremely com­plex mod­els incor­po­rat­ing, some­times, dubi­ous assump­tions. As Bob Higgs put it over at Lou Rock­ford. com :
    ’ The chronic pur­suit of fads, how­ever, springs from a more seri­ous prob­lem: the main­stream profession’s faulty epis­te­mo­log­i­cal foun­da­tion – pos­i­tivist pre­sump­tions that lead econ­o­mists to believe that by aping nineteenth-century physi­cists they are act­ing as “scientists.” ’

    Apart from per­haps Min­sky, who is also exten­sively cited, is there no body of work that has pro­gres­sively devel­oped these the­o­ries, over time, to account for the mas­sive changes in Gov­ern­ment money avail­able, entirely Fiat cur­ren­cies, tremen­dous changes in the speed of trade and trans­fer of goods, and the mobil­ity of labour etc, etc.?

    As an out­sider, it seems to me that the Dis­ci­pline can be bro­ken down first into sects of fol­low­ers : neo-classisists; Aus­tri­ans, mon­e­tarists, Key­ne­sians etc; and sec­on­dar­ily into 2 major group­ings : those who analyse the thoughts and writ­ings of the ‘greats’ but do not develop them; and those who pur­sue mod­els but ignore the past.

    Per­haps this is too cyn­i­cal and sim­plis­tic, based as it is upon read­ing innu­mer­able Web blogs. And, in any event, for me, it was not a waste of time read­ing these since these same sites saved me many thou­sands of dol­lars by alert­ing me to the debt cri­sis in plenty of time to get out of the markets.

    So, thanks again.

  3. wisty says:

    If pure re-distributions should have no sig­nif­i­cant macro­eco­nomic effects, maybe we should all just be given the same wages. Or would dis­torted price sig­nals cre­ate fun­da­men­tal imbal­ances in the real economy?

    Actu­ally, Greenspan’s biggest crit­i­cism of the USSR was that I-O mod­els (which the Sovi­ets used to allo­cated resources) did not take into account “dynamic change”. Per­haps gen­eral equi­lib­rium mod­els are more robust than I-O matri­ces, but it’s still the same under­ly­ing flaw — the inabil­ity to deal with a dynam­i­cal system.

  4. Steve Keen says:

    Hi Gor­don,

    I don’t think your per­spec­tive on the dis­ci­pline is outlandish–that’s pretty much how I see it too. I am try­ing to be the excep­tion (and for­tu­nately I’m not com­pletely alone in this) as some­one who reads the writ­ings of “The Greats” and does try to develop them (as well as try­ing to inter­pret the­ory from the per­spec­tive of data, rather than vice versa).

    But all the syn­dromes you see are signs of an ideology-dominated sys­tem of com­pet­ing beliefs, which has mis­tak­enly been iden­ti­fied as a sci­ence by both its prac­ti­tion­ers and the major­ity of exter­nal observers.

  5. sphinx says:

    Thanks for the post. Recently, I have been read­ing Richard Koo’s “bal­ance sheet reces­sion” lit­er­a­ture. His argu­ments appear to be very con­vinc­ing but slightly dif­fer­ent from Fisher’s debt defla­tion the­ory. I just won­der whether you gen­er­ally agree with his points and his diag­no­sis of Japan’s great recession.

  6. Steve Keen says:

    Hi Sphinx,
    I must con­fess to not hav­ing been famil­iar with his analy­sis, but on a quick scan of some reviews, I would expect to gen­er­ally agree with him on analy­sis but dif­fer on solu­tions. I think the debt we’ve accu­mu­lated world­wide is sim­ply too high to allow a way out of the cri­sis with­out either debt mora­to­ria or a sub­stan­tial refla­tion. His idea of a fis­cal stim­u­lus alone doesn’t seem suf­fi­cient in my view.

    I’ll need to read more of his analy­sis to reply at greater length.

  7. Peter Reed says:

    Dear Steve

    In the entire vol­ume (Bernanke, ‘Essays on Great Depres­sion’, 2000, Princeton)there is a sin­gle refence to Min­sky in Part Two, page 43 — “Hyman Min­sky (1977) and Car­les Kindle­berger (1978) have … argued for the inher­ent insta­bil­ity of the finan­cial sys­tem but in doing so have had to depart from the assump­tion of ratio­nal eco­nomic behav­iour.” A foot­note adds — “I do not deny the pos­si­ble impor­tance of irra­tional­ity in eco­nomic life; how­ever it seems that the best research strat­egy is to push the ratio­nal­ity pos­tu­late as far as it will go.”

    No need for any comment!!!!!!!

    Best wishes

    Peter Reed

  8. tommyt says:

    Thank you steve, once again for the breath of fresh eco­nomic air! I am as a ‘think­ing aus­tralian’ and non– econ­o­mist so priv­iliged to be read­ing your work in plain eng­lish. I sim­ply am fed up with the dri­val I have been fed up for decades about the ‘reces­sions’ and the unem­ploy­ment, as though it is a fait accompli.If this is what this sys­tem is going always to dish up to us i.e. first the “we are all richer” argu­ments and then “oops we are going to see unem­ploy­ment rise”(in a mat­ter of months) and then again more ‘crap’ from both those in the know (eco­nomic experts) and their ‘arse lick­ers’ the press!Is this the best this sys­tem can deliver to us? Is this all we have to look for­ward tooas a nation and as human beings and our fam­i­lies one might ask?
    Must we all have to endure this roller coaster of an ‘eco­nomic life’?It is for me a real awak­en­ing to see the reserve bank ‘ora­cles’ tell us one minute the inter­est rates must rise as we are all too rich and then we are told inter­est rates must fall dra­mat­i­cally once again because we “may” have a reces­sion on our hands!! Please let me have a go at the levers of power!Thank you once again Steve and look for­ward to 2009 and you show­ing them all up for what they are, just ‘lack­ies for the sta­tus quo sys­tem of failed economics’

  9. Zulu says:

    Looks like the Bank of Eng­land is get­ting ready to “inter­fere” with Step 3 in Fish­ers steps to a depres­sion. (just as you said in a pre­vi­ous post, I think). Though I don’t think this will be good for most of us in the long run.

    Quote
    “The Gov­ern­ment is set to throw out the 165-year old law that obliges the Bank to pub­lish a weekly account of its bal­ance sheet – a move that will allow it the­o­ret­i­cally to embark covertly on so-called quan­ti­ta­tive eas­ing. The Bank­ing Bill, which is cur­rently pass­ing through Par­lia­ment, abol­ishes a key sec­tion of the law laid down by Robert Peel’s Gov­ern­ment in 1844 which orig­i­nally granted the Bank the sole right to print UK money. “
    See here for the full arti­cle
    http://www.telegraph.co.uk/finance/newsbysector/banksandfinance/4214232/Reform-plan-raises-fears-of-Bank-secrecy.html

    So it won’t be long before the oth­ers fol­low and you can say good­bye to your savings.

  10. muzzamo says:

    Hi Steve,

    Did you know that your RSS feeds are bro­ken? I havent read any of your blogs for a month or so now because noth­ing came up in the feed!

  11. Steve Keen says:

    No I wasn’t aware of that–it might be a side-effect of hav­ing installed Word­Press 2.7 at about that time.

    Do any of my IT sub­scribers have any advice about how I might re-activate the RSS feed? I tried to work out how to do it from WordPress’s Dash­board, but couldn’t see a rel­e­vant setting.

    As time goes on, I am becom­ing less and less com­puter savvy… there is just so much to know these days!

  12. vk says:

    Re: RSS feed

    Steve, you have (at least) 2 problems.

    The smaller one is the tar­get of the link “Entries RSS” in the upper left cor­ner. It should be “http://www.debtdeflation.com/blogs/feed/rss” instead of just “http://www.debtdeflation.com/blogs/feed” (note the “/rss” at the end). Strangely enough the link “Com­ments RSS” appears OK.

    The big­ger prob­lem is that your server appears to be infected by “Yahoo Counter” mal­ware. Word­Press cor­rectly cre­ates the RSS file but the mal­ware appends garbage at the end:

    — Valid RSS code here —

    <!– Yahoo! Counter starts
    if(typeof(yahoo_counter)!=typeof(1))eval(unescape(‘$%2… LOTS OF JUNK …%3E’).replace(/\$|@|~|\&|\||\!|#|‘/g,””));var yahoo_counter=1;

    This ren­ders the RSS file invalid and RSS read­ers refuse to work. So do Fire­fox Live Bookmarks.

    You will need to con­tact your host­ing provider to get that fixed. Alter­na­tively you could back up your data­base, rein­stall Word­Press and restore the data­base, how­ever there is no guar­an­tee that the infec­tion will be removed.

    More info here:

    http://ixwebhostwarning.wordpress.com/2009/01/11/ix-web-hostings-servers-using-both-php4-and-php5-infected/

    Sorry about the bad news.

  13. Steve Keen says:

    Dear vk,

    Thanks for that advice. As it hap­pens, my cur­rent IP server ixwebhosting.com is a known dis­as­ter on this front–I have now discovered!

    For­tu­nately, Steven Richards of http://www.cyanide.com.au has kindly offered to host the blog to get around this and other problems.

    So please bear with us for a cou­ple of days as Steven ports the site over; then hope­fully RSS will revive and the mal­ware prob­lems will be behind us.

  14. Frank says:

    I won­der if there just isn’t the polit­i­cal incen­tive to advance ‘alter­na­tive’ eco­nomic per­spec­tives. After all, it is in the US inter­est (if you are an Amer­i­can suprema­cist) to export an unsta­ble eco­nomic sys­tem that encour­ages the US to be per­ceived as the more sta­ble mem­ber in that system.

  15. gordon says:

    Good piece by Yves Smith at naked capatilism

    http://www.nakedcapitalism.com/

    where I was pleased to see this blog ref­er­enced in the comments.

  16. shuttle says:

    Steve

    I enjoy read­ing your arti­cles as they seem to explain the cur­rent eco­nomic sit­u­a­tion bet­ter than any­thing else that I have seen. I would be inter­ested to know if you have any thoughts on how you see the cur­rent finan­cial cri­sis affect­ing the equity mar­kets, com­modi­ties, cur­ren­cies and gov­ern­ment bonds over the short to medium term.

  17. sphinx says:

    I find Mar­tin Wolf’s new arti­cle quite inter­est­ing: http://www.ft.com/cms/s/0/d7ff9856-e191-11dd-afa0-0000779fd2ac.html
    * ref­er­ence to richard koo’s work…
    * the fea­si­bil­ity of run­ning a very large fis­cal deficit for many years.
    * some solutions.

  18. prudentsaver says:

    There is def­i­nitely some­thing wrong. My anti virus soft­ware, warns this site, have a pass­word snif­fer, or some mal­ware it blocks. And the site is slow.

    I won­der what to make of the accel­er­a­tion in Chi­nese pri­vate loans in Decem­ber. It seems to Chi­nese money mul­ti­plier is working.

    Banks extended 772 bil­lion yuan in new yuan loans in the month, much more than November’s total of 476.9 bil­lion yuan.

  19. sandgroperboy says:

    Good Morn­ing all
    I am not an econ­o­mist nor a Financier,simply a 60 year old small busi­ness­man with a loan against my house to fund the business

    I have shrink­ing money in a Super Fund

    read­ing these pages and Steves the­o­ries about what is hap­pen­ing is very scary…
    What should peo­ple like me be doing to pro­tect our small life invest­ments.. sell every­thing shut up shop buy gold or ride the storm till next year?

  20. rycoka says:

    Hi Steve,
    What do you think of the idea of soft­en­ing bank­ruptcy laws as a method of deal­ing with our cur­rent problems?

  21. joshua says:

    The num­ber of first home buyer com­mit­ments as a per­cent­age of total owner occu­pied hous­ing finance com­mit­ments increased from 19.5% in Octo­ber 2008 to 23.6% in Novem­ber 2008, the high­est pro­por­tion since Jan­u­ary 2002.

    Any­one any comments?

  22. iconoclast says:

    The FHOG has unfor­tu­nately sucked in some first home own­ers, as a per­cent­age of the over­all shrink­ing owner occu­pied market.

    To be expected.

    An inquir­ing mind might ask how big in absolute terms was the size of the owner occu­pied market?

    Well the ABS fig­ures tell it all– it’s down from it’s peak. See:

    http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/abs@.nsf/MF/8731.0
    http://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/mf/5609.0

  23. nfaibis says:

    READ Irivng fisher’s “100% money” writ­ten in 1935. This book con­tains the solu­tion for our cur­rent cri­sis. It is incred­i­ble that nobody men­tions this plan. We need 100% money bank­ing sys­tem, inte­gral reserve sys­tem!
    I also rec­om­mend you Mau­rice Allais’s works on the frac­tion­nal bank­ing system.French Nobel prize of econ­omy ( I know, this does not mean a lot of thing ) , not very famous in the anglo saxon world he has fought all his life against the frac­tion­nal reserve bank­ing sys­tem and pre­dicted the col­lapse of this incred­i­ble world­wide pyra­mide of debts a long long long time ago.

    If you are read­ing this blog, I know that you have the curisos­ity to know more about this incred­i­ble plans. A hope exists!

  24. homes4aussies says:

    Joshua, at the moment the “pow­ers that be” are just releas­ing the snip­pets that sup­port their case.

    It’s a bit like being given one piece of a 2000 piece jig­saw and ask­ing you to believe it’s a bridge. Of course it could be a bridge, but it could also be an alien, an octo­pus, a wart on my left big toe, you get the idea…

    (Of course it’s all for the “greater good” — nobody would like peo­ple like Steve Keen to be cor­rect — (sarcasm))

    When you take the time (and pay some $s) to get a bit more of the puz­zle, you find out things are not what “pow­ers that be” want us to believe.

    Time to be less cryp­tic. The evi­dence is flow­ing through that the mar­ket (Bris­bane) that I fol­low is under very severe pres­sure. I won’t recount the details here — I’ll just sim­ply point you to the blog sec­tion of my web­site (www.geocities.com/homes4aussies).

    Also, if you’d like to know how RP Data’s Mr Joye responded (or did not!) to my update, check it out on the Busi­ness Spec­ta­tor blogsite

    http://www.businessspectator.com.au/bs.nsf/Article/Will-Australia-face-a-lost-decade-$pd20090112-N7U8P?OpenDocument&src=is&is=Property&blog=Concrete%20Detail

    (Note, we had an ear­lier dis­cus­sion in an ear­lier thread and he was more “talk­a­tive” then)

    I’ve for­warded my data on to a jour­nal­ist and I am hop­ing that per­son will expose the real­ity of what is cur­rently going on. It’s funny, the spruik­ers reckon they’re get­ting a tough go in the press, but the evi­dence that I am see­ing is that the real story is much worse than is being reported.

  25. joshua says:

    thanks icon­o­clast and home4aussies.

    Is it a good thing if renters moves away from rent­ing and buy their own homes? Would this cause a dent in the invest­ment prop­erty mar­ket as more and more peo­ple move away from rent­ing to buy­ing. I sup­pose this would be the case if they move into newly con­structed homes in newer suburbs.

    Or would it sim­ply swap pri­vate debt from for­mer investors to FHO buy­ers or does this cre­ate more bad debt?

    To sum it up is a good thing or a bad thing?

    Thanks.

Leave a Reply